Skip to main content
Log in

The inventor’s role: was Schumpeter right?

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

According to Schumpeter, the creative process of economic development can be divided into the stages of invention, innovation (commercialization) and imitation. Each stage is associated with specific skills. This paper examines whether Schumpeter’s assertion was correct, i.e. whether the invention and innovation stages should be undertaken by different agents. In addition, we examine whether there is a rationale for the Schumpeterian entrepreneur to include the inventor in the commercialization process. Combining the abilities of the entrepreneur and the inventor may serve to facilitate customer adaptation, strengthen knowledge transfers and reduce uncertainty, thereby expanding market opportunities. Based on a unique database covering Swedish patents granted to individuals and small firms, the empirical analysis shows that profitability increases by 22 percentage points when inventions are commercialized by the entrepreneur instead of by inventors. However, active involvement of the inventor is shown to have a significantly positive impact on profitability, irrespective of commercialization mode.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Taking all firms into account, irrespective of size, there has been a clear tendency in the 20th century towards an increased vertical integration of inventive (R&D) and producing activities, according to, for instance, Teece (1988) and Aghion and Howitt (1998). Others challenge those findings and claim that technological progress and institutional changes have facilitated a vertically dispersed production structure (Arora et al. 2001; Grossman and Helpman 2002).

  2. In fact, Teece (2006) stress the importance of empirical research, addressing precisely these issues.

  3. A related strand of the literature focuses on differences in individual capabilities (Carroll and Hannan 2000), or the interaction between the characteristics of opportunity and the characteristics of the people who exploit them (Casson 2005). Schumpeter also considered individual’s psychological capacity as the key in identifying opportunities.

  4. Here we adopt the somewhat modified version, as introduced by Bianchi and Henrekson (2005). See also Giarratana (2004) who, studying a niche of the software industry, show that whether inventors are turned into entrepreneurs depend on entry costs, the “height” of the invention, and property rights.

  5. They were more aligned on other aspects of entrepreneurship. For instance, both Knight and Schumpeter shared the belief that entrepreneurial talent was a scarce resource. Such scarcity is not so much associated with entrepreneurs’ alertness, or with their professionalism, as with their psychology. More recently, Lazear (2005) suggests that entrepreneurs possess more balanced talents that span a number of skills. This could be argued to strengthen their “combinatorial capacity”, as compared to the more limited role of specialists. In the perspective of the issue we raise, the entrepreneur could be viewed as being endowed with multi-task talent, while the inventor is more of a specialist (Lindbeck and Snower 2000).

  6. See Frankel (1955), Teece (1988) and Aghion and Howitt (1992).

  7. Where p = q 0 e + r(E), q 0 > 0. See Aghion and Howitt (1998) for details.

  8. Arora (1995) presents an alternative model for the specific case in which tacit knowledge (embodied in the inventor) can be bundled with arm’s length licensing contracts. The decisive factor is strong IPRs, which promote commercialization and a functioning market for know-how.

  9. Or, as noted in Teece (2006), partly based on Penrose (1959), partly on Schumpeter (1911).

  10. Note Scherer’s (1980) contribution, in which it is claimed that innovative entry by entrepreneurs and innovative entry by large firms seem to fulfill complementary roles in the process of turning an innovation into full-scale, welfare enhancing new production activities. Major innovations often emanate in a serendipitous way from individual entrepreneurs (Baumol 2007).

  11. As noted by Mansfield et al. (1981), it takes imitators about four years to duplicate an invention for approximately 65% of the original costs. Process technology innovation tends to leak somewhat slower than product innovation (Mansfield 1985).

  12. Teece (1986) discusses this in terms of ccumulative innovations.

  13. Mansfield (1968) was perhaps the first to observe that there was no statistical relationship between concentration in an industry and rate of technological change.

  14. See also Gans et al. (2007), analyzing the impact of uncertainty and timing of entry, either as a start-up or in terms of licensing high-technology products.

  15. The type of innovation could also influence the strategic choice of entry, i.e. whether it is radical or incremental and to what extent the innovation challenges technological or organizational knowledge. Innovation characterized as a reshuffling of the way in which different components are linked to each other while the core concept remains—architectural innovation—often takes place in larger firms and gives smaller firms an innovative edge in terms of more flexibility (Henderson and Clark 1990).

  16. We would expect inventors and innovators to be endowed by heterogeneous ability as regards information activities. It depends on their technological and market knowledge, i.e. learning from previous experience and occupation (van Hayek 1937; Frank 1988). Hence, it can be assumed that inventors possess more technological knowledge and less market knowledge, whereas the opposite is the case for the entrepreneur.

  17. Very few studies have used questionnaires. See, for instance, Griliches (1990).

  18. A highly promising and recent research initiative is the PatVal-EU project (Giuri et al. 2007). The ambition is to gather data through questionnaires sent out to a large number of EU-countries (presently six countries are covered). The questionnaire targets inventors and will focus on data related to value of patents, source of innovations, degree and mode of commercialization, etc. Gambardella et al. (2007) implement the PatVal-EU database to analyze the determinants of licensing. Their study deviates from the current insofar as the focus of the current paper is the profitability of commercialization and the role of the inventor in the commercialization process.

  19. In 1998, 2,760 patents were granted in Sweden; 776 of these were granted to foreign firms, 902 to large Swedish firms with more than 1,000 employees, and 1,082 to Swedish individuals and firms with less than 1,000 employees. In the pilot survey carried out in 2002, it turned out that large Swedish firms refused to provide information on individual patents. Furthermore, it proved very difficult to persuade foreign firms to fill in questionnaires about patents. These firms were mostly large multinationals firms. Therefore, the population consists of 1,082 patents granted to Swedish individuals and firms with less than 1,000 employees.

  20. All inventions do not result in patents. However, since an invention, which does not result in a patent, is not registered anywhere, there are two problems in empirically analyzing the invention rather than the patent. First, it is impossible to find these new ideas, products and developments among all firms and individuals. On the other hand, all patents are registered. Second, even if the “inventions” are found, it is difficult to judge whether they are sufficient improvements to be called inventions. Only the national and international patent offices make such judgements. Therefore, the choice of the patent rather than the invention is the only alternative for an empirical study of the commercialization process.

  21. The database was collected in 2003–04. The year the patent is granted is used here, but patents filed in a specific year might have been preferable. The choice of patents granted in a specific year is, however, not a problem in the statistical estimations.

  22. Each patent always has at least one inventor and often also an applying firm. The inventors or the applying firm can be the owner of the patent, but the inventors can also indirectly be owners of the patent, via the applying firm. Sometimes the inventors are only employed in the applying firm which owns the patent. If the patent had more than one inventor, the questionnaire was sent to one inventor only.

  23. The group of individual inventors includes private persons and self-employed inventors as well as two-three inventors who are organized in trading companies or private firms without employees.

  24. For a vast majority of the patents, the commercialization had reached such a stage that there was no uncertainty at all about the performance.

  25. It is very complicated to estimate profit flows, because most firms have many products in their statement of account, and many individuals do not have any statement of account at all.

  26. There were 86 observations in the database, where the owner could not specify the expected profit level of the commercialization. These missing values could also be treated as a fourth, uncertain, outcome of PERFORM. A multinomial logit model, where all four alternatives were included, was estimated. Then, we performed a test for independence of irrelevant alternatives (Hausmann and McFadden 1984). When excluding the uncertain alternative in the multinomial logit model, this test cannot be rejected. Thus, the parameter estimates between the other outcome alternatives are almost unaffected if the uncertain alternative is excluded. Then there is no problem in excluding those patents with unknown profit-levels from the estimations.

  27. Note that this is not a two-step Heckman model. No lambda is computed and used in the second step.

  28. The alternative to measuring the owner’s patent stock at the grant date does not alter the results of the estimations.

  29. A technology class must have at least one observation in each of the three outcome alternatives, to obtain an own technology dummy. Technology classes without enough observations are instead merged with other closely related classes (Breschi et al. 2004).

  30. The difference is that a probit model is used in the first step of the present model, whereas Svensson (2007) used survival models.

  31. GOVRD measures how large a share of the R&D-costs that was financed from the government. Similarly, PRIVRD and OTHRD measure how large shares of this financing were from private venture capitalists and research foundations/universities, respectively. OWNER measures how large a share (in percent) of the patent that is directly or indirectly owned by the inventors. The dummy variable KOMPL takes on the value of 1 if complementing patents are needed to create a product, and 0 otherwise. INVNMBR measures the number of inventors of the patent.

  32. These estimations are available from the authors upon request.

  33. Among the 530 commercialized patents in the sample, there are 460 unique owners (firms/inventors), 418 owners only have one commercialized patent, 29 owners have two patents, and only 13 owners have at least three patents. Dummies can only be assigned to those 42 owners with at least two patents. The multicollinearity problems occurred even when all technology and region dummies were excluded and when dummies were only included for those 13 owners with at least three commercialized patents.

References

  • Abernathy W, Utterback J (1978) Patterns of industrial innovation. Technol Rev 80:40–47

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60:323–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1998) Endogenous growth theory. MIT, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Arabsheibani G, De Meza D, Maloney J, Pearson B (2000) And a vision appeared to them of great profit: evidence of self-deception among the self-employed. Econ Lett 67:35–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arora A (1995) Licensing tacit knowledge: intellectual property rights and the market for know-how. Econ Innov New Technol 4:41–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arora A, Fosfuri A, Gambardella A (2001) Markets for technology. The economics of innovation and corporate strategy. MIT, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Arthur B (1989) Competing technologies, increasing returns, and lock-in by historical events. Econ J 99:116–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol W (2007) Small firms: why market-driven innovation can’t get along without them. Paper presented at the IFN conference in Waxholm

  • Bianchi M, Henrekson M (2005) Is the neoclassical entrepreneur really entrepreneurial? Kyklos 58:353–377

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breschi S, Lissoni F, Malerba F (2004) The empirical assessment of firms. Technological coherence: data and methodology. In: Cantwell A, Gambardella A, Granstrand O (eds) The economics and management of technological diversification. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Carroll GR, Hannan MT (2000) The demography of corporations and industries. Princeton, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Casson M (2005) Review of Scott Shane. A general theory of entrepreneurship. Small Bus Econ 24:423–430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cutler RS (1984) A study of patents resulting from NSF chemistry program. World Pat Inf 6:165–169

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • David P (1985) Clio and the economics of QWERTY. Am Econ Rev 75:332–337

    Google Scholar 

  • De Meza D, Southey C (1996) The borrower’s curse: optimism, finance and entrepreneurship. Econ J 106:375–386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank MZ (1988) An intertemporal model of industrial exit. Q J Econ 103:333–344

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel M (1955) Obsolescence and technological change in a maturing economy. Am Econ Rev 52:995–1022

    Google Scholar 

  • Fraser S, Greene FJ (2006) The effects of experience on entrepreneurial optimism and uncertainty. Economica 73:169–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gambardella A, Giuri P, Luzzi A (2007) The market for patents in Europe. Res Policy 36:1163–1183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gans J, Stern S (2003) The product market and the market for ideas: commercial strategies for technology entrepreneurs. Res Policy 32:333–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gans J, Hsu DH, Stern S (2007) The impact of uncertain intellectual property rights on the market for ideas: evidence from patent grant delays. NBER WP 13234. Cambridge

  • Giarratana M (2004) The birth of a new industry: entry by start-ups and the drivers of firm growth. The case of the encryption software. Res Policy 33:787–806

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giuri P, Mariani M, Brusoni S, Crespi G, Francoz D, Gambardella A, Garcia-Fontes W, Geuna A, Gonzales R, Harfhoff D, Hoisi K, Le Bas C, Luzzi A, Magazzinin L, Nesta L, Nomaler Ö, Palomeras N, Patel P, Romanelli M, Verspagen B (2007) Inventors and invention processes in Europe: results from the PatVal-EU survey. Res Policy 36:1107–1127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (1997) Econometric analysis, 3rd edn. Prentice-Hall, Upper Saddle River

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (2002) Econometric modeling guide, vol 1, Limdep version 8.0. Econometric Software Inc., Plainview

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z (1990) Patent statistics as economic indicators: a survey. J Econ Lit 28:1661–1707

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z, Hall BH, Pakes A (1987) The value of patents as indicators of inventive activity. In: Dasqupta P, Stoneman P (eds) Economic policy and technological performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman G, Hart O (1986) The costs and benefits of ownership: a theory of lateral and vertical integration. J Polit Econ 94:691–719

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman G, Helpman E (2002) Integration versus outsourcing in industry equilibrium. Q J Econ 117:85–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall BH (1993) The stock market valuation of R&D investment during the 1980s. Am Econ Rev 83:259–264

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann J, McFadden D (1984) A specification test for the multinomial logit model. Econometrica 52:1219–1240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson R, Clark K (1990) Architectural innovation: the reconfiguration of existing product technologies and the failure of established firms. Adm Sci Q 35:9–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner IM (1973) Competition and entrepreneurship. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight F (1921) Risk, uncertainty and profit. Houghton Mifflin, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Lazear EP (2005) Entrepreneurship. J Labor Econ 23:649–680

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lieberman M, Montgomery D (1988) First mover advantage. Strateg Manage J 9:41–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck A, Snower D (2000) Multitask learning and the reorganization of work: from tayloristic to holistic organization. J Labour Econ 18:353–376

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield E (1968) Industrial research and technological innovation: an econometric analysis. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield E (1985) How rapidly does new industrial technology leak out? J Ind Econo 34:217–233

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield E, Schwartz M, Wagner S (1981) Imitation costs and patents: an empirical study. Econ J 91:907–918

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maurseth PB (2005) Lovely but dangerous: the impact of patent citations on patent renewal. Econ Innov New Technol 14:351–374

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pakes A (1986) Patents as options: some estimates of the value of holding European patent stocks. Econometrica 54:755–784

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Penrose E (1959) The theory of the growth of the firm. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell W (1990) Neither markets nor hierarchies: network forms of organization. In: Staw B, Cummings L (eds) Research in organizational behaviour. JAI, Greenwhich

    Google Scholar 

  • Rossman J, Sanders BS (1957) The patent utilization study. Pat, Trade-mark Copyr J Res Educ 1:74–111

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanders BS (1962) Speedy entry of patented inventions into commercial use. Pat, Trade-mark Copyr J Res Educ 6:87–116

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanders BS (1964) Patterns of commercial exploitation of patented inventions by large and small corporations. Pat, Trade-mark Copyr J Res Educ 8:51–92

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanders BS, Rossman J, Harris LJ (1958) The economic impact of patents. Pat, Trade-mark Copyr J Res Educ 2:340–362

    Google Scholar 

  • Schankerman M, Pakes A (1986) Estimates of the value of patent rights in European countries during the post-1950 period. Econ J 96:1052–1076

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scherer F (1980) Industrial market performance and economic performance. Rand McNally, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmookler J (1966) Invention and economic growth. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1911) The theory of economic development. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1942) Capitalism, socialism, democracy. Harper and Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1947) The creative response in economic history. J Econ Hist 7:149–159

    Google Scholar 

  • Shane S, Venkataraman S (2000) The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research. Acad Manage Rev 25:217–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • SRI International (1985) NSF engineering program patent study. Menlo Park, CA

  • Svensson R (2002) Commercialization of Swedish patents: a pilot study in the medical and hygiene sectors. IUI Working paper no. 583. IUI, Stockholm

  • Svensson R (2007) Commercialization of patents and external financing during the R&D-phase. Res Policy 36:1052–1069

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece D (1986) Profiting from technological innovation. Res Policy 15:285–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece D (1988) Technological change and the nature of the firm. In: Dosi G (ed) Technical change and economic theory. Pinter, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece D (2006) Reflections on ‘profiting from innovation’. Res Policy 35:1131–1146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Hayek F (1937) Economics and knowledge. Economica 4:879–891

    Google Scholar 

  • Wennekers S, Thurik R (1999) Linking entrepreneurship and economic growth. Small Bus Econ 13:27–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu B, Knott AM (2006) Entrepreneurial risk and market entry. Manage Sci 52:1315–1330

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Erik Mellander, Magnus Henrekson, Lars Persson and seminar participants at the annual EARIE conference in Valencia, the Max Planck Conference in Bangalore and the Oslo Entrepreneurship Workshop (where the paper was awarded the price of “Best paper in Entrepreneurship and Innovation”), for constructive comments. Jakob Eliasson provided excellent research assistance. The Bank of Sweden Tercentenary Foundation, Marianne and Marcus Wallenberg Foundation, and Torsten and Ragnar Söderberg’s Foundation are acknowledged for generous financial support. Finally, the paper has benefited from insightful comments in the referee process to this journal.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pontus Braunerhjelm.

Appendix

Appendix

Table 9 Explanatory variables included in the probit sample selection equation
Table 10 Estimation of dummy variables, model I
Table 11 Estimation of dummy variables, model II

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Braunerhjelm, P., Svensson, R. The inventor’s role: was Schumpeter right?. J Evol Econ 20, 413–444 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-009-0157-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-009-0157-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation