Skip to main content
Log in

The Effect of Political Competition on Democratic Accountability

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Political Behavior Aims and scope Submit manuscript

An Erratum to this article was published on 11 December 2012

Abstract

Representing uncompetitive, homogeneous constituencies is increasingly the norm for American legislators. Extensive research has investigated how competition affects the way representatives respond to their constituents’ policy preferences. This paper explores competition’s effect on the other side of representation, how constituents respond to their legislators’ policy record. Combining multiple measures of state competitiveness with large-N survey data, I demonstrate that competition enhances democratic accountability. Voters in competitive states are more interested in politics, more aware of the policy positions their U.S. senators have taken, and more likely to hold them accountable for those positions at election time. Robustness checks show that these effects are not due to the intensity of campaigning in a state: general competition, not particular campaign activities, drives citizens’ response. The recent increase in uncompetitive constituencies has likely lessened the degree to which legislators are held accountable for their actions in office.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Political competition refers to the degree of (potential) conflict of preferences between groups within a constituency (Bishin 2003, p. 1). Previous research has not settled on a common terminology for this competition, also referring to it as “complexity” (Ensley et al. 2009), “discord” (Fitzgerald and Curtis 2012), “diversity” (Putnam 2007), or “heterogeneity” (Anderson and Paskeviciute 2006; McAtee and Wolak 2011). Throughout this paper, I use the terms “political competition”, “diversity”, and “heterogeneity” interchangeably.

  2. Common Cause, see http://www.commoncause.org/site/pp.asp?c=5nJCJQPvEhKUE&b=7461781; the League of Women Voters, http://ca.lwv.org/lwvc/action/redistrict/; Americans for Redistricting Reform, http://www.americansforredistrictingreform.org/html/redistricting_reform_principle.html, all accessed July, 2011.

  3. A separate literature explores how media coverage of politics—and in particular, of incumbent legislators’ records—varies across contexts (e.g. Arnold 1990; Hutchings 2003). Assessing the quality of the information communicated by the media in competitive states is beyond the scope of this paper. Instead, I focus on the narrower claim from social arena studies that political competition drives interest in politics, and thus increases information-seeking.

  4. Concerns about the representativeness of Internet sampling are significant but less germane to this research design, which rests on comparing differences between respondents in competitive and uncompetitive states rather than measuring absolute levels of knowledge or vote choice in the electorate. Nonetheless, the sample represents the electorate of 2006 very closely in vote choice and demographic characteristics (Vavreck and Rivers 2008).

  5. Residents of Hawaii and Indiana were also surveyed but are excluded from these analyses. Measures of ideological disagreement at the state level are only available for the 48 contiguous states. In Indiana, incumbent Senator Dick Lugar faced no major party challenger and won 87 % of the vote, making the state a distinct outlier in the vote choice models.

  6. Updated measures of ideological disagreement using a more recent survey such as the 2004 NAES are not yet available. Levendusky and Pope (2010) also estimate the same measure using the 2006 CCES survey data, including the seven roll call vote questions used here. To avoid problems of endogeneity in using the same survey source, I rely on their estimates from the 2000 NAES. Empirically, the measures are correlated at .48 for the states in this analysis, suggesting that using the 2000 measure should not significantly bias the results.

  7. Table A1 in the Online Appendix gives the rank and value of each measure for the states in this analysis.

  8. Specifically, comparing the sum of squared residuals from a multi-level Poisson model to the residual degrees of freedom results in a ratio of 1.1, with a p-value of .001 based on the χ2 distribution.

  9. As a robustness check to assess whether one item among the seven roll call votes may be influencing the results unduly, Table A3 in the Online Appendix presents the results from a series of regression models that replicate the analysis in Table 2, dropping one of the roll call votes from the scale each time. The estimated effects of state competition on knowledge of the incumbent’s record are consistent across all of these specifications, offering little evidence that individual items in the aggregate scale are skewing the results.

  10. The substantive results obtained from models that use actual levels of congruence rather than perceptions are near-identical to those presented here, as we might expect given the strong correlation between them shown in Table 3.

  11. Additionally, estimating models that include the campaign intensity variables but exclude the state competition variables does not suggest any significant relationship between the two. Incumbent fundraising is very weakly but positively related to the weight constituents place on policy congruence (.08, SE = .04, p = .08) but overall there is little suggestion that campaign factors alter the structure of vote choice (see Table A6 in the Online Appendix). As a final robustness check, I estimated models that allowed all of the individual-level coefficients to vary by state. If the interest-priming hypothesis is correct, then political competition should prime citizens to weigh their policy interests more heavily, but should not alter the weights they place on other elements (party congruence and retrospective evaluations of the economy and of Iraq). The results from these models, available in Table A4 in the Online Appendix, show no significant effect of political competition on the other individual-level covariates. The fact that political competition affects the importance of policy congruence, but not party or retrospective evaluations, is more evidence for H2. I am grateful to one of the anonymous reviewers for suggesting this additional test of the theory.

  12. Note that these results are independent of the overall level of policy congruence in the electorate. That is, the first differences show the differences between a voter who perceives 25 % congruence and a voter who perceives 75 % congruence in each of these types of states. As Table A1 in the Online Appendix shows, significant numbers of voters perceive high or low levels of policy congruence in all types of states, with high and low levels of political competition.

References

  • Abramowitz, A. I., Alexander, B., & Gunning, M. (2006). Incumbency, redistricting, and the decline of competition in U.S. house elections. Journal of Politics, 68(1), 75–88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aistrup, J. A. (2004). Constituency diversity and party competition: A county and state level analysis. Political Research Quarterly, 57(2), 267–281.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Ferrara, E. L. (2000). Participation in heterogeneous communities. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), 847–904.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Baqir, R., & Easterly, W. (1999). Public goods and ethnic divisions. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 1243–1284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, C. J., & Paskeviciute, A. (2006). How ethnic and linguistic heterogeneity influence the prospects for civil society: A comparative study of citizenship behavior. Journal of Politics, 68(4), 783–802.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ansolabehere, S., & Jones, P. E. (2010). Constituents’ responses to congressional roll call voting. American Journal of Political Science, 54(3), 583–597.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, R. D. (1990). The logic of congressional action. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bailey, M., & Brady, D. W. (1998). Heterogeneity and representation: The senate and free trade. American Journal of Political Science, 42(2), 524–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauer, D. J., & Sterba, S. K. (2011). Fitting multilevel models with ordinal outcomes: Performance of alternative specifications and methods of estimation. Psychological Methods, 16(4), 373–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bishin, B. G. (2003). Democracy, heterogeneity and representation: Explaining representational differences across states. Legislative Studies Section Newsletter, 26(1).

  • Bishin, B. G., Dow, J. K., & Adams, J. (2006). Does democracy “suffer” from diversity? Issue representation and diversity in senate elections. Public Choice, 129, 201–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bishop, B. (2008). The big sort. Houghton Mifflin.

  • Bond, J. R. (1983). The influence of constituency diversity on electoral competition in voting for congress, 1974–1978. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 8(2), 201–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browne, W. J., Subramanian, S. V., Jones, K., & Goldstein, H. (2005). Variance partitioning in multilevel logistic models that exhibit overdispersion. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 168(3), 599–613.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunell, T. L. (2008). Redistricting and representation: Why competitive elections are bad for America. Routledge.

  • Bullock, C. S., & Brady, D. W. (1983). Party, constituency, and roll-call voting in the U.S. senate. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 8(1), 29–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, D. E. (2006). Why we vote: How schools and communities shape our civic life. Princeton University Press.

  • Campbell, J. E., & Jurek, S. J. (2003). The Decline of competition and change in congressional elections. In S. Ahuja & R. Dewhirst (Eds.), Congress responds to the twentieth century. Ohio State University Press.

  • Costa, D. L., & Kahn, M. E. (2003). Civic engagement and community heterogeneity: An economist’s perspective. PS: Political Science and Politics, 1(1), 103–111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dennis, C., Bishin, B. G., & Nicolaou, P. (2000). Constituent diversity and congress: The case of NAFTA. Journal of Socio-Economics, 29(4), 349–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elston, D. A., Moss, R., Boulinier, T., Arrowsmith, C., & Lambin, X. (2001). Analysis of aggregation, a worked example: numbers of ticks on red grouse chicks. Parasitology, 122, 563–569.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ensley, M. J., Thomas, M. W., & de Marchi, S. (2009). District complexity as an advantage in congressional elections. American Journal of Political Science, 53(4), 990–1005.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn, J. (1986). Incumbent performance and electoral control. Public Choice, 50(1–3), 5–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fieldhouse, E., & Cutts, D. (2010). Does diversity damage social capital? A comparative study of neighbourhood diversity and social capital in the US and Britain. Canadian Journal of Political Science, 43(2), 289–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M. P. (1974). Representatives, roll calls, and constituencies. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M. P. (1981). Retrospective voting in American national elections. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fitzgerald, J., & Curtis, K. A. (2012). Partisan discord in the family and political engagement: A comparative behavioral analysis. Journal of Politics, 74(1), 129–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gastil, J., & Dillard, J. P. (1999). Increasing political sophistication through public deliberation. Political Communication, 16(1), 3–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gelman, A., & Hill, J. (2007). Data analysis using regression and multilevel/hierarchical models. Cambridge University Press.

  • Gerber, E. R., & Lewis, J. B. (2004). Beyond the median: Voter prederences, district heterogeneity, and political representation. Journal of Political Economy, 112(6), 1364–1383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gimpel, J. G., Lay, J. C., & Schuknecht, J. E. (2003). Cultivating democracy: Civic environments and political socialization in America. Brookings Institution.

  • Glaser, J. M. (2003). Social context and inter-group political attitudes: Experiments in group conflict theory. British Journal of Political Science, 33, 607–620.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griffin, J. D. (2006). Electoral competition and democratic responsiveness: A defense of the marginality hypothesis. Journal of Politics, 68(4), 911–921.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gronke, P. (2001). The electorate, the campaign, and the office: A unified approach to senate and house elections. University of Michigan Press.

  • Gulati, G. J. (2004). Revisiting the link between electoral competition and policy extremism in the U.S. congress. American Politics Research, 32(5), 495–520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Habyarimana, J., Humphreys, M., Posner, D. N., & Weinstein, J. M. (2007). Why does ethnic diversity undermine public goods provision? American Political Science Review, 101(4), 709–725.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huckfeldt, R., Mendez, J. M., & Osborn, T. (2004). Disagreement, ambivalence, and engagement: The political consequences of heterogeneous networks. Political Psychology, 25(1), 65–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hutchings, V. L. (2003). Public opinion and democratic accountability: How citizens learn about politics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobson, G. C. (2004). The politics of congressional elections. New York: Pearson Longman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, D. R. (2003). Position taking and position avoidance in the U.S. senate. Journal of Politics, 65(3), 851–863.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, P. E. (2011). Which buck stops here? Accountability for policy positions and policy outcomes in congress. Journal of Politics, 73(3), 764–782.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahn, K. F., & Kenney, P. J. (1999). The spectacle of U.S. senate campaigns. Princeton University Press.

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuklinski, J. H. (1977). District competitiveness and legislative roll-call behavior: A reassessment of the marginality hypothesis. American Journal of Political Science, 21(3), 627–638.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Raja, R. (2009). Redistricting: Reading between the lines. Annual Review of Political Science, 12, 203–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levendusky, M. S., & Pope, J. C. (2010). Measuring aggregate-level ideological heterogeneity. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 35(2), 259–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lodge, M., & Hamill, R. (1986). A partisan schema for political information processing. American Political Science Review, 80, 505–519.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luttmer, E. F. P. (2001). Group loyalty and the taste for redistribution. Journal of Political Economy, 109(3), 6–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McAtee, A., & Wolak, J. (2011). Why people decide to participate in state politics. Political Research Quarterly, 64(1), 45–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mutz, D. C. (2002). Cross-cutting social networks: Testing democratic theory in practice. American Political Science Review, 96(1), 111–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oliver, J. E. (2001). Democracy in suburbia. Princeton University Press.

  • Oliver, J. E., & Ha, S. E. (2007). Vote choice in suburban elections. American Political Science Review, 101(3), 393–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pacheco, J. S. (2008). Political socialization in context: The effect of political competition on youth voter turnout. Political Behavior, 30, 415–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pildes, R. H. (2006). The constitution and political competition. New York University Public Law and Legal Theory Working Papers. Paper 27.

  • Putnam, R. D. (2007). E Pluribus Unum: Diversity and community in the twenty-first century. Scandinavian Political Studies, 30(2), 137–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rahn, W. M. (1993). The role of partisan stereotypes in information processing about political candidates. American Journal of Political Science, 37(2), 472–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samples, J., & McDonald, M. P. (Eds.) (2006). The marketplace of democracy: Electoral competition and American politics. Brookings Institution.

  • Scheufele, D. A., Hardy, B. W., Brossard, D., Waismel-Manor, I. S., & Nisbet, E. (2006). Democracy based on difference: Examining the links between structural heterogeneity, heterogeneity of discussion networks, and democratic citizenship. Journal of Communication, 56, 728–753.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, C. R., Brady, D. W., Brody, R. A., & Ferejohn, J. A. (1990). Linking constituency opinion and senate voting scores: A hybrid explanation. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 15(4), 599–621.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinclair, B. (1990). Washington behavior and home-state reputation: The impact of national prominence on senators’ images. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 15(4), 475–494.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sullivan, J. L. (1973). Political correlates of social, economic and religious diversity in the American states. Journal of Politics, 35, 70–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vavreck, L., & Rivers, D. (2008). The 2006 cooperative congressional election study. Journal of Elections, Public Opinion, and Parties, 18(4), 355–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verba, S., Schlozman, K. L., & Brady, H. E. (1995). Voice and equality: Civic voluntarism in American politics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weissberg, R. (1979). Assessing legislator-constituency policy agreement. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 4, 605–622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I thank Steve Ansolabehere, Barry Burden, Claudine Gay, Jason Mycoff, Joe Pika, Meg Rithmire, Sid Verba, and in particular Ben Bishin for helpful comments on previous versions of this paper. I am also grateful to the journal’s three anonymous reviewers who helped clarify and strengthen the argument substantially. All errors are, of course, my own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Philip Edward Jones.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

PDF (76 KB)

Appendix: Model Specifications

Appendix: Model Specifications

Interest model

In the models predicting constituents’ interest in politics (shown in Table 1), all of the coefficients except for the intercept are fixed. The individual-level model can be written as follows:

$$ \begin{aligned} \hbox{Political interest}_{ij} =& \beta_{0j} + \beta_{1j}(\hbox{Female})_{ij} + \beta_{2j}(\hbox{Age})_{ij} + \beta_{3j}(\hbox{Income})_{ij} + \beta_{4j}(\hbox{Black})_{ij} + \beta_{5j}(\hbox{Hispanic})_{ij} + \beta_{6j}(\hbox{Other race})_{ij}\\ &\quad + \beta_{7j}(\hbox{High school})_{ij} + \beta_{8j}(\hbox{Some college})_{ij} + \beta_{9j}(\hbox{College})_{ij} + \beta_{10j}(\hbox{Post-college})_{ij} + r_{ij} \end{aligned} $$

where i indexes individuals, j indexes states, and r ij represents the residual for individual i in state j. At the state level, β0j is modeled as a function of several state-level variables (as an example, for Model 1(a) in Table 1):

$$ \begin{aligned} \beta_{0j} =& \gamma_{00} + \gamma_{01}(\hbox{Turnout 2004})_{j} + \gamma_{02}(\hbox{High school graduates})_{j} + \gamma_{03}(\hbox{Electoral competition})_{j} + \mu_{0j}\\ \hbox{and} & \quad \beta_{pj} = \gamma_{p0}\quad \hbox{for}\,\, \hbox{p}=1-10 \end{aligned} $$

The full model is obtained by substituting the second model into the first one. Since the dependent variable is a categorical variable, I use an ordered logistic regression model (see Bauer and Sterba 2011). The knowledge models in Table 2 and the congruence models in Table 3 take the same approach, using a Poisson and least squares estimator respectively.

Vote choice model

In the models predicting constituents’ vote choice for or against the incumbent senator (shown in Table 4), all of the coefficients except for the intercept and policy congruence are fixed. The individual-level model can be written as follows:

$$ \begin{aligned} \hbox{Vote choice}_{ij} =& \beta_{0j} + \beta_{1j}(\hbox{Policy congruence})_{ij} + \beta_{2j}(\hbox{Co-partisan})_{ij} + \beta_{3j}(\hbox{Independent})_{ij} + \beta_{4j}(\hbox{Don't know senator's party})_{ij}\\ &\quad+ \beta_{5j}(\hbox{Economy gotten worse})_{ij} + \beta_{6j}(\hbox{Economy stayed same})_{ij} + \beta_{7j}(\hbox{Economy gotten better})_{ij} \\ &\quad + \beta_{8j}(\hbox{Economy gotten much better})_{ij} + \beta_{9j}(\hbox{Don't know economy})_{ij} + \beta_{10j}(\hbox{Iraq war not a mistake})_{ij} \\ &\quad+ \beta_{11j}(\hbox{Don't know Iraq war})_{ij} + r_{ij} \end{aligned} $$

where i indexes individuals, j indexes states, and r ij represents the residual for individual i in state j. At the state level, β0j and β1j are modeled as a function of several state-level variables (as an example, for Model 1(a) in Table 4):

$$ \begin{aligned} \beta_{0j} =& \gamma_{00} + \gamma_{01}(\hbox{Turnout 2004})_{j} + \gamma_{02}(\hbox{High school graduates})_{j} + \gamma_{03}(\hbox{GOP senator})_{j} + \gamma_{04}(\hbox{Electoral competition})_{j} + \mu_{0j}\\ \beta_{1j} =& \gamma_{10} + \gamma_{11}(\hbox{Turnout 2004})_{j} + \gamma_{12}(\hbox{High school graduates})_{j} + \gamma_{13}(\hbox{GOP senator})_{j} + \gamma_{14}(\hbox{Electoral competition})_{j} + \mu_{1j}\\ \hbox{and}& \quad \beta_{pj} = \gamma_{p0}\quad \hbox{for}\,\, \hbox{p}=2-11 \end{aligned} $$

The full model is obtained by substituting the second model into the first one.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Jones, P.E. The Effect of Political Competition on Democratic Accountability. Polit Behav 35, 481–515 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-012-9203-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-012-9203-3

Keywords

Navigation