Skip to main content
Log in

What Motivates Gifts? Intra-Family Transfers in Rural Malawi

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Family and Economic Issues Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper uses Family Transfers Project data collected in rural Malawi during 1999 to ascertain the motivation for gift-giving using discriminating hypotheses. The study models monetary and monetized gifts sent and received between the survey respondents and their parents, their children, and their siblings as a function of sender and receiver characteristics. Individual analyses are compared with household level models to reveal that both individual and household characteristics can matter in different cases. OLS, Probit and Tobit models are compared to conclude that, as with other similar studies, a wide range of motivations exist including altruism, (co-)insurance, and an inheritance motive. Motivations differ slightly depending upon the relationship between the sender and receiver, however, no single motive can be attributed to any given relationship.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. When even pure altruists would not have an incentive to give, but are shown to do so, this is termed the “warm glow” motive to giving (see e.g. Crumpler and Grossman 2008). We would like to thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this as an alternative explanation. Interestingly Cowley et al. (2004) find that some families give gifts to their church which have a negative impact on the family’s financial situation. This suggests either some social pressure or else non-financial compensation such as the “warm glow” motive.

  2. This is particularly important in an agricultural economy such as Malawi. For example, households living in different areas might implicitly agree to send each other transfers whenever one has suffered from drought and the other not. Alternatively, urban and rural income may follow different patterns making it possible to share income through implicit transfer agreements in order that when one household suffers a negative shock, it is supported by the other.

  3. An additional motivation can be found by distinguishing between giving to one’s children and the ultimate aim of “dynastic altruism” or the “survival of the gene” (see e.g. Horioka 2002; Fan 2005).

  4. We would like to thank an anonymous referee for pointing this out.

  5. “Felicity” is used here in order to distinguish between total utility (derived from both one’s own consumption and the consumption of the other) and the utility derived only from one’s own consumption, which has been called ‘felicity’. For example, the Giver’s Utility = f(Utility of Receiver; His/Her own Felicity) where his/her own felicity is derived from his/her own consumption.

References

  • Agarwal, R., & Horowitz, A. W. (2002). Are international transfers altruism or insurance? Evidence from Guyana using multiple-migrant households. World Development, 30(11), 2033–2044.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amuedo-Dorantes, C., & Pozo, S. (2004). Workers’ transfers and the real exchange rate: A paradox of gifts. World Development, 32(8), 1407–1417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amuedo-Dorantes, C., & Pozo, S. (2006). Transfers as insurance: Evidence from Mexican immigrants. Journal of Population Economics, 19, 227–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azam, J. P., & Gubert, F. (2004). Those in Kayes: The impact of transfers on their recipients in Africa. Institute d’Economie Industrielle (IDEI) Working Paper Series, 308.

  • Bloom, D. E., & Stark, O. (1985). The new economics of labor migration. American Economic Review, 75(2), 173–178.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cao, H. (2006). Time and financial transfers within and beyond the family. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 27(2), 375–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conroy, A. C., Blackie, M. J., Whiteside, A., Malewezi, J. C., & Sachs, J. D. (2006). Poverty, AIDS and hunger: Breaking the poverty trap in Malawi. New York: Palgrave MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowley, E. T., Paterson, J., & Williams, M. (2004). Traditional gift giving among pacific families in New Zealand. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 25(3), 431–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, D. (1987). Motives for private income transfers. Journal of Political Economy, 95(3), 508–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crumpler, H., & Grossman, P. J. (2008). An experimental test of warm glow giving. Journal of Public Economics, 92(5–6), 1011–1021.

    Google Scholar 

  • De la Brière, B., Sadoulet, E., de Janvry, A., & Lambert, S. (2002). The roles of destination, gender, and household composition in explaining transfers: An analysis for the Dominican Sierra. Journal of Development Economics, 68, 309–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dercon, S. (1996). Risk, crop choice and savings: Evidence from Tanzania. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 44(3), 485–514.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fafchamps, M., Udry, C., & Czukas, K. (1998). Drought and saving in West Africa: Are livestock a buffer stock? Journal of Development Economics, 55(2), 273–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fan, C. S. (2005). Survival of the gene, intergenerational transfers and precautionary saving. Journal of Development Economics, 77, 451–479.

    Google Scholar 

  • Funkhouser, E. (1995). Remittances from international migration: A comparison of El Salvador and Nicaragua. Review of Economics and Statistics, 77(1), 137–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grigorian, D. A., & Melkonyan, T. A. (2008). Microeconomic implications of transfers in an overlapping generations model with altruism and self-interest. IMF Working Paper WP/08/19.

  • Gupta, R., & Hegde, S. A. (2009). An exploratory study of financial remittances among non-resident Indians in the United States. Journal of the Family and Economic Issues, 30(2), 184–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayhoe, C. R., & Stevenson, M. L. (2007). Financial attitudes and inter vivos resource transfers from older parents to adult children. Journal of the Family and Economic Issues, 28(1), 123–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horioka, C. Y. (2002). Are the Japanese selfish, altruistic, or dynastic? Japanese Economic Review, 53, 26–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ilahi, N., & Jafarey, A. (1999). Guestworker migration, transfers and the extended family: Evidence from Pakistan. Journal of Development Economics, 58, 458–512.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koh, S.-K., & MacDonald, M. (2006). Financial reciprocity and elder care: Interdependent resource transfers. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 27(3), 420–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laferrère, A., & Wolff, F. C. (2006). Microeconomic models of family transfers. In S. Kolm & J. M. Ythier (Eds.), Handbook of economics of giving, altruism and reciprocity 2 (pp. 889–969). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. B., & Stark, O. (1985). Motivations to remit: Evidence from Botswana. Journal of Political Economy, 93(5), 901–918.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mauss, M. (1990). The gift: The form and reason for exchange in archaic societies, Original title: Essai sur le don, Presses Universitaires de France, 1950, Trans. Hall, W.D., London: Routledge.

  • Morah, E. U. (2007). Are people aware of their HIV-positive status responsible for driving the epidemic in sub-saharan Africa? The case of Malawi. Development Policy Review, 25(2), 215–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mtika, M. M., & Doctor, H. V. (2002). Matriliny, patriliny, and wealth flows in rural Malawi. African Sociological Review, 6(2), 71–97.

    Google Scholar 

  • Naufal, G. S. (2008). Why remit? The case of Nicaragua. Institute for the Study of Labor Discussion Paper, IZA DP 3276.

  • Platteau, J. P. (1997). Mutual insurance as an elusive concept in traditional rural communities. Journal of Development Studies, 33(6), 764–796.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rapoport, H., & Docquier, F. (2006). The economics of migrants’ transfers, on the economics of giving, reciprocity and altruism. In S. Kolm & J. M. Ythier (Eds.), Handbook of economics of giving, altruism and reciprocity 2 (pp. 1135–1198). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J. D., & Warner, A. M. (2001). Natural resources and economic development: The curse of natural resources. European Economic Review, 45, 827–838.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Secondi, G. (1997). Private monetary transfers in rural China: Are families altruistic? Journal of Development Studies, 33(4), 487–511.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sheng, X., & Killian, T. S. (2009). Over time dynamics of monetary intergenerational exchanges. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 30(3), 268–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Takane, T. (2007). Customary land tenure, inheritance rules, and smallholder farmers in Malawi. Institute of Developing Economies Discussion Paper No.104.

  • Udry, C. (1990). Credit markets in northern Nigeria: Credit as insurance in a rural economy. The World Bank Economic Review, 4(3), 251–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Dalen, H. P, Groenewold, G., & Fokkema, T. (2005). Transfers and their effect on emigration intentions in Egypt, Morocco and Turkey. Tinbergen Institute Discussion paper, TI 2005-030/1.

  • VanWey, L. K. (2004). Altruistic and contractual transfers between male and female migrants and households in rural Thailand. Demography, 41(4), 739–756.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weinreb, A. A. (2001). Substitution and substitutability: The effects of kin availability on intergenerational transfers in Malawi. In A. H. Gauthier, C. Chu, & S. Tuljapurkar (Eds.), The distribution of private and public resources across generations. Oxford: Oxford University Press/IUSSP.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weinreb, A. A. (2002). Lateral and vertical intergenerational exchange in rural Malawi. Journal of Cross-Cultural Gerontology, 1(38), 101–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White, H. (1980). Heteroscedasticity consistent covariance matrix and a direct test for heterscedasticity. Econometrica, 48, 817–838.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Simon Davies.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Davies, S. What Motivates Gifts? Intra-Family Transfers in Rural Malawi. J Fam Econ Iss 32, 473–492 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10834-010-9216-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10834-010-9216-1

Keywords

Navigation