1 Introduction

Climate policy is affected by multiple decision makers at local, national, and international levels. Usually these decision makers are not fully coordinated in terms of goals and methods, and the existence of several layers of governance may encourage strategic behavior from powerful local actors trying to enhance their own positions (Caillaud et al. 1996). Multi-level climate policy governance is also related to governance of local air pollutants since production processes often involve emitting several air pollutants simultaneously and most emission control measures affect more than one pollutant. Environmental policies aiming at reducing \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions might therefore create spillovers, i.e., reductions or increases in emissions of other pollutants by firms changing or modifying their production processes in response to climate policy. For example, a common strategy to reduce \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions is switching the fuel mix from fuel oil to biofuels, which are counted as having zero carbon. However, although such a transition may make \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions fall dramatically, biofuels often imply an increase in nitrogen oxides (\(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}})\), particulate matter (PM), carbon monoxide (CO), and volatile organic compound (VOC) emissions (Brännlund and Kriström 2001).

Spillovers from climate policy have important implications for policy design since they affect the cost of climate regulations. Theory shows that one critical factor determining whether an increased stringency of climate policies leads to increased emission of local pollutants is the elasticity of substitution (e.g., Ambec and Coria 2013). If pollutants are substitutes, \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions will be reduced at the expense of increased emissions of local pollutants. If they are complements, climate policies might lead to ancillary benefits since local pollutants will then be reduced alongside \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions. There is also the effect of technological development, which generally decreases the emissions of all pollutants. Therefore, emissions of pollutants that are substitutes to \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) can still fall with climate policy if technological development outweighs the substitution effect. In this paper, we characterize changes in the relative performance of Swedish combined heat and power plants with respect to \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions in response to variations in the level of stringency of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) policies and multiple layers of regulation. In particular, we study the effects of the interaction between the European Union Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) and the Swedish \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) tax and refundable charge on \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions with the goal of determining whether multi-level climate policy governance has generated ancillary benefits or costs in terms of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions. To this end, we built a unique dataset of Swedish combined heat and power plants for the period 2001–2009 consisting of detailed boiler-level data on not only production and inputs but also \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions. We estimate a quadratic directional output distance function to study and compare patterns of technical progress, substitution between \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\), and shadow prices of these pollutants in the period 2001–2004 (before introduction of the EU ETS) and 2005–2009 (post-implementation).

To the best of our knowledge, this is the first study analyzing and quantifying the effects of the multi-governance of climate change policy and its interaction with the other national policy instruments aimed to reduce local pollutants. However, some previous studies have employed directional output distance functions to analyze the shadow cost of environmental regulations (see e.g., Färe et al. 2005; Marklund and Samakovlis 2007; Wei et al. 2013; Du et al. 2015a, b) and the technological non-separability and substitutability among air and water pollutants (see e.g., Murty et al. 2007; Kumar and Managi 2011; Färe et al. 2012). Notably, Agee et al. (2014) estimate a multiple-input, multiple-output directional output distance function to analyze the technological non-separability in the control of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions of the U.S. electric utilities’ sector and its implications for the design of a \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions cap and trade system. They find that controlling one pollutant also controls the other, and hence there are ancillary benefits from policies targeted at reducing one of them. Their results are consistent with those of Burtraw et al. (2003), who employ an electricity market equilibrium model to simulate changes in emissions resulting from different climate policy scenarios and find considerable (health-related) ancillary benefits due to reduced \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions.

Our work differs from previous studies in two important ways. First, we focus on policy-induced substitutability across pollutants and the changes in relative shadow prices of emissions introduced by environmental multi-level governance. Second, we analyze the case of Sweden who has been at the forefront of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emission reduction for a long time, and it is one of the few countries whose present level of emissions is below the level recorded in 1990. This accomplishment is mainly explained by the remarkable expansion of biofuel use, which has the potential negative side effect of increasing \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions. Hence, compared with the U.S., where switching from high-carbon fuels (like coal and oil) to reduced-carbon ones such as natural gas is still an option, in Sweden most emission reductions have already been undertaken. Our results indicate that there are limits to the positive spillovers (i.e., ancillary benefits) from climate policy as countries approach the goal of a carbon-free economy. Furthermore, the existence of spillovers indicates the need for better coordination across policymakers at different levels of governance, and policy coordination becomes even more important under substitutability since the unintended costs of climate policy on local pollution can make it less acceptable to the public and policymakers. This is particularly the case since the benefits from reduced climate change mostly accrue in the long term and on a global scale, while any ancillary costs of climate policy would tend to accrue in the near term, affecting the countries undertaking mitigation action.

This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 briefly describes the climate and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) policy in Sweden and the changes in the relative price of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) over the period 2001–2009. Section 3 presents the theoretical and empirical framework of the joint production of heat and power, \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions. Section 4 discusses the data and empirical results and analyzes the sensitivity of our results to different directional vectors. Section 5 discusses some policy implications and Sect. 6 concludes the paper.

2 Climate and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) Policy for Combined Heat and Power Plants in Sweden: Carbon Taxation, EU ETS, and the Refundable \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) Charge

Combined heat and power (hereinafter CHP) is the simultaneous generation of useful heat and power from a single fuel or energy source at or close to the point of use. As in all combustion processes, \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions produced by CHP depend mainly on the carbon content of the fuel, while \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions and the interactions between measures to control \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions vary according to the design characteristics of the individual plants. For instance, compression-ignition engines generally operate with lower air-to-fuel ratios and higher combustion temperatures, which results in higher \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions per unit of power generated. Alternatively, the use of spark-ignition gas engines operated on natural gas would enable CHP to reduce \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions, albeit with a small increase in \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions. Moreover, \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) is produced largely from an unintended chemical reaction between nitrogen and oxygen in the combustion chamber. The process is quite non-linear in temperature and other parameters of the combustion process, which implies that there is a large scope for \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) reduction through various technical measures. For example, it is possible to reduce \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions by operating at lower engine efficiency or through the investment in post-combustion technologies (PCTs) that clean up \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) once it has been formed. However, such technologies usually require energy and thus will increase \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions (at least relative to output). It is also possible to invest in combustion technologies (CTs) involving the optimal control of combustion parameters (temperature, pressure, stoichiometry, flame stability and homogeneity, and flue gas residence time) to inhibit the formation of thermal and prompt \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\). The adoption of these technologies clearly depends on the investment costs, which have shown to be boiler and plant specific and vary with boiler capacity (Linn 2008). Moreover, some technologies are not commercially available below certain size thresholds (Sterner and Turnheim 2009).Footnote 1

Since most emission control measures employed by CHP plants affect both \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions, one should observe some changes in pollutants’ substitutability in response to the variations in the level of stringency of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) policies and multiple layers of regulations.Footnote 2 Therefore, in order to develop a hypothesis regarding the relative incentives to reduce \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions, respectively, we start by briefly describing climate and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) policies in Sweden and the evolution of the relative cost of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) per unit of output over the period 2001–2009 (for a detailed description of Swedish environmental policy see SEPA 2007).

In 1991, Sweden introduced a carbon tax that is directly connected to the carbon content of the fuel. Initially, the tax was equivalent to 25 €/metric ton of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\). After increasing steadily over the last decade, it currently corresponds to 105 €/ton.Footnote 3 Since the tax is very high and Sweden is a small open economy, there has been concern for the competitiveness of some energy-intensive industries. Thus, a number of deductions and exemptions have been created in those sectors that are open to competition, and a series of reduced tax rates have been introduced. In the case of the heat and power sector, the carbon tax varies according to the type of generation, i.e., whether the generating unit is a CHP boiler or an only-heat boiler. From 2005 to June 2008, the carbon tax and the EU ETS overlapped. At that point, the tax was essentially replaced with the EU ETS, and CHP plants were granted a tax reduction of 85%. Since the level of the price of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) allowances is much lower than the Swedish tax level, this harmonization with the EU actually has implied a sizeable fall in the price of carbon emissions for most CHP plants.

The tax reform of 1991 introduced not only a carbon tax but also other taxes including a high fee on \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\). The fee was initially confined to \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions from electricity and heat-producing boilers, stationary combustion engines, and gas turbines with a useful energy productionFootnote 4 of at least 50 gigawatt hours (GWh) per year (approx. 182 boilers). However, because of its effectiveness in reducing emissions and simultaneously falling monitoring costs, in 1996 the charge system was extended to include all boilers producing at least 40 GWh of useful energy per year, and in 1997 the limit was again lowered to 25 GWh.

The total fees are refunded to the participating plantsFootnote 5 in proportion to their production of useful energy. Hence, the system encourages plants to reduce \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions per unit of energy to the largest possible extent, since plants with lower emissions relative to energy output are net receivers of the refund. The fee was originally set at 4.3 €/kg, which is an extremely high level compared to other countries.Footnote 6

The Swedish \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) fee has been evaluated extensively (see e.g., Höglund 2005; Sterner and Höglund 2006; Sterner and Turnheim 2009; Bonilla et al. 2015). It has been shown to be very effective in lowering emissions. Empirical findings suggest that extensive emission reductions have taken place due to learning and technological development in abatement. Nevertheless, emissions fell mostly in the early years. The decrease has continued since then, but at a reduced pace. Hence, as the impact of the charge seemed to diminish, in 2008 the Swedish government decided to raise the fee to 5.3 €/kg to foster further adoption of more effective treatment techniques (SEPA 2003, 2007, 2009).

How have the regulations described above affected the relative cost of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions? To assess the overall picture is not altogether easy. Although large industrial plants in the energy sector can to some extent adjust their technology in response to short-run price variations (e.g., through fuel switching), many features of their design take a decade to build and are adapted to expected price trends over a longer time horizon (e.g., the ability to switch fuels may well be one such feature). Furthermore, the carbon tax paid and allowances used depend on the type of fuel being burned, which is endogenous to the stringency of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) policies in previous years.Footnote 7 To provide an indication of the relative stringency of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) policies, we compute the relative cost of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions per unit of output for the CHP plants in our data (see Fig. 1). The cost of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions is calculated as the sum of the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) tax plus the EU ETS price, while the cost of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions corresponds to the fee on \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\). As shown in Fig. 1, it seems clear that over the period 2001–2009, policy signals in Sweden told power companies to avoid fossil fuels. The cost of emitting \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) is much higher than the cost of emitting \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\). For example, in 2003, an average CHP plant emitted 0.082 tons of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and 0.248 kg of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) to produce 1 MWh of useful energy. Given the magnitude of the carbon tax and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) fee at that time, this implied a cost of 6.116 and 0.936 €/MWh for \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions, respectively. This is to say that the cost of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions per unit of output was over six times the cost of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions.

The variation observed in Fig. 1 suggests that \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) policy did become less stringent (relative to \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}})\) due to the carbon tax phase-out. Indeed, the reduction began already in 2004 when CHP plants were granted a significant carbon tax reduction.Footnote 8 Furthermore, Sweden increased the fee on \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) for all regulated boilers in 2008, adding to the effect of the reduced carbon tax on the relative cost of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\).

A clear hypothesis to be derived from the analysis above is that firms should direct most abatement efforts to reducing \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions as the economic effect of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) regulations on firms’ profitability (taking into account both abatement costs and abatement benefits through reduced pollution payments) is much higher than that of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) regulations. Moreover, the variations in the relative cost of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions should have induced some variations in the relative \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) abatement efforts if generating units were to minimize the cost of compliance with environmental regulations. The magnitude and direction of the changes in the optimal mix of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions would depend, however, on a series of factors such as technological development and whether \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) are substitutes or complements in abatement. For instance, in the absence of technological development, one would expect emissions of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) from CHPs to decrease relatively more in 2005–2009 than 2001–2004 if pollutants are substitutes, while the reverse holds if pollutants are complements. On the other hand, the high relative cost of reducing \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions should have also triggered technological fixes and fuel switching aiming to reduce them. Hence, given the relative stringency of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) regulations, we would expect technological efforts to be overall biased towards \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emission reductions. In the next sections, we use a quadratic directional output distance function to derive the relative shadow prices of emissions for each generating unit and analyze the changes on technical efficiency and abatement efforts induced by the regulatory changes, but first we will describe the estimation strategy.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Relative cost of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions per MWh for CHP plants. Note The cost of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions is calculated as the sum of the carbon tax plus the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) EU ETS price (mean of forward contracts 2007–2013). We compute the relative cost of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions per MWh per boiler and average the values across boilers

3 Estimation Strategy

One of the main objectives of this paper is to quantitatively characterize the degree of substitutability or complementarity between reductions of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions. The technical efficiency literature provides a variety of methods to evaluate the performance of the generating units, including nonparametric and parametric approaches. Since substitutability is associated with the curvature along the output possibilities set (see Färe et al. 2005), in our approach we employ a parametric directional output distance function that is twice differentiable to derive estimates of elasticities of substitution output/pollutants and between pollutants.Footnote 9 We also estimate technical efficiencies and absolute and relative shadow prices of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\).

In the past, researchers have first estimated a production function frontier and then the distances of individual plants from the frontier. The function used here seeks the simultaneous expansion of good outputs and contraction of bad outputs, which is very suitable to our case. Modeling the technology in this manner allows for the adoption of abatement measures in order to reduce the bad outputs (emissions) and still increase, or hold constant, the production of heat and power.

Following Färe et al. (2005), we treat emissions as bad or undesirable outputs generated in the boilers’ combustion process and model jointly the production of heat and power and emissions. Let the set of output possibilities \(P(x)=\left\{ {({y,b}){:}\,x \hbox { can produce}\,({y,b})} \right\} \) represent all feasible input–output possibilities of boilers that jointly generate heat and power (y) and a vector of emissions \(b=( {b_1, b_2 })\) (where \(b_1 \) represents emissions of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(b_2 \) represents emissions of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}})\) using an input vector \(x=( {x_1, x_2, x_3})\) containing installed capacity, fuel consumption (as input energy) and labor, respectively. We assume that inputs are strongly disposable, which implies that the output set is not shrinking if the inputs are expanding. Furthermore, we assume null-jointness, implying that no good output is produced without a positive amount of at least one of the bad outputs. Moreover, all outputs are assumed to be jointly weakly disposable, implying that bad outputs are not freely disposable and cannot be reduced without affecting the production of good outputs, i.e., through the diversion of inputs into pollution reduction. Finally, we consider that the good output is strongly disposable, implying that if an observed good and bad output vector is feasible, then any output vector with less of the good output is also feasible (i.e., good outputs are freely disposable since they have a nonnegative value). The directional output distance function is characterized as

$$\begin{aligned} \vec {D}_{0}({x,y,b;g}) = { max}\left\{ {\gamma {:}\,\left( {y + \gamma {g_y},{b_1} - \gamma {g_{{b_1}}},{b_2} - \gamma {g_{{b_2}}}} \right) \in P(x)} \right\} . \end{aligned}$$
(1)

Equation (1) is a functional representation of the technology that is consistent with P(x) and its associated properties. The solution \(\gamma ^{*}=\vec {D}_{o}(x,y,b;g)\) corresponds to the maximum expansion and contraction of good and bad outputs, respectively. The directional vector \(g=\left( {g_y, g_{b_1 }, g_{b_2 } } \right) \) specifies in which direction the good and bad outputs are scaled so as to reach the boundary of the output set at \(\left( {b_1 -\gamma ^{*}g_{b_1 }, b_2 -\gamma ^{*}g_{b_2 }, y+\gamma ^{*}g_y } \right) \).

The directional output distance function has several properties listed below (see Färe et al. 2005):

  1. (1)

    \(\vec {D}_o ({x,y,b;g})\ge 0\) if and only if \(\left( {y, b} \right) \) is an element of P(x)

  2. (2)

    \(\vec {D}_o \left( {x,y^{\prime },b;g} \right) \ge \vec {D}_o ({x,y,b;g})\) for \(\left( {y^{\prime }, b} \right) \le \left( {y, b} \right) \in P(x)\)

  3. (3)

    \(\vec {D}_o \left( {x,y,b^{\prime };g} \right) \ge \vec {D}_o ({x,y,b;g})\) for \(\left( {y, b^{\prime }} \right) \ge \left( {y, b} \right) \in P(x)\)

  4. (4)

    \(\vec {D}_o \left( {x^{\prime },y,b;g} \right) \ge \vec {D}_o ({x,y,b;g})\) for \(x^{\prime }\ge x\in P(x)\)

  5. (5)

    \(\vec {D}_o ({x,y,b;g})\) is concave in \(\left( {y, b} \right) \in P(x)\)

  6. (6)

    \(\vec {D}_o \left( {x,\lambda y,\lambda b;g} \right) \ge 0\) for \(\left( {y, b} \right) \in P(x)\) and \(0\le \lambda \le 1\)

  7. (7)

    If \(\vec {D}_o \left( {x,y,0;g} \right) <0\) for \(y>0\), then \(\left( {y, 0} \right) \notin P(x)\)

  8. (8)

    \(\vec {D}_o \left( {x,y+\rho g_y,b_1 -\rho g_{b_1 } ,b_2 -\rho g_{b_2 } ;g} \right) =\vec {D}_o ({x,y,b;g})-\rho , \rho \in \mathfrak {R}\),

Property (1) points out that \(\vec {D}_o ({x,y,b;g})\) is non-negative for feasible output vectors. Thus, the function takes the value of zero for generating units with efficient output vectors on the boundary of P(x) or takes positive values for generating units operating inefficiently below the boundary. Higher values of \(\vec {D}_o ({x,y,b;g})\) indicate higher inefficiency. \(\vec {D}_o ({x,y,b;g})\) also satisfies monotonicity: (2) indicates that it is non-increasing in good output, (3) states that it is non-decreasing in undesirable outputs, and (4) points out that it is non-decreasing in inputs. Property (5) indicates that the output set frontier is concave in good and bad outputs. \(\vec {D}_o ({x,y,b;g})\) also satisfies (6) weak disposability of good output and bad outputs, and (7) null jointness. Additionally, the directional output distance function satisfies the translation property. Under this property, which corresponds to expression (8), the inefficiency can decrease by the amount of \(\rho \) if bad outputs are contracted by \(\rho g_{b_1}\) and \(\rho g_{b_2}\), and the good output is expanded by \(\rho g_y\).

We specify our directional output distance function with a quadratic form to ensure that the frontier is a twice differentiable function.Footnote 10 For a generating unit k operating at period t, the directional output distance function corresponds to

$$\begin{aligned}&\vec {D}_{o}^{t}\left( x_{k}^{t},y_{k}^{t},b_{k}^{t};g \right) \nonumber \\&\quad =\alpha + \sum _{n=1}^3 {\alpha _{n}x_{nk}^{t}} +\beta _{1}y_{k}^{t}+ \sum _{i=1}^2 {\theta _{i}b_{ik}^{t}} +\frac{1}{2} \sum _{n=1}^3 \sum _{n^{\prime }=1}^3 {\alpha _{nn'}x_{nk}^{t}x_{n^{\prime }k}^{t}} +\frac{1}{2}\beta _{2}\left[ y_{k}^{t} \right] ^{2}\nonumber \\&\qquad +\,\frac{1}{2} \sum _{i=1}^2 \sum _{i^{\prime }=1}^2 {\theta _{ii^{\prime }}b_{ik}^{t}} b_{i^{\prime }k}^{t}+ \sum _{n=1}^3 \sum _{i=1}^2 {\eta _{ni}x_{nk}^{t}b_{ik}^{t}} +\sum _{i=1}^2 {\mu _{i}y_{k}^{t}b_{ik}^{t}}\nonumber \\&\qquad +\,\sum _{n=1}^3 {\delta _{n}x_{nk}^{t}y_{k}^{t}} +\tau _{t}+\varsigma _{f}, \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where \(k=1,2,\ldots , K;\,t=1,2,\ldots , T\); \(\tau _t \) are fixed effects per year and \(\varsigma _f \) are fixed effects per firm. In order to estimate the directional output distance function in (2), we minimize the sum of the deviations of the estimated distance function from the efficient value of zero, subject to the constraints (1)–(9). That is,

\(\min {\sum }_{t=1}^T {\sum }_{k=1}^K \left[ \vec {D}_{o}^{t}\left( x_{k}^{t},y_{k}^{t},b_{k}^{t};g \right) -0 \right] \), subject to

  1. (1)

    \(\vec {D}_{o}^{t}\left( x_{k}^{t},y_{k}^{t},b_{k}^{t};g \right) \ge 0,\forall k,t.\)

  2. (2)

    \(\partial {\vec {D}_{o}^{t}\left( x_{k}^{t},y_{k}^{t},b_{k}^{t};g \right) }\big /{\partial b_{i}}=\theta _{i}+\theta _{ii}b_{ik}^{t}+\frac{1}{2}\left( \theta _{ii^{\prime }}+\theta _{i^{\prime }i} \right) b_{i^{\prime }k}^{t}+{\sum }_{n=1}^3 {\eta _{ni}x_{nk}^{t}+} \mu _{i}y_{k}^{t}\ge 0\,\,\forall i,k,t.\)

  3. (3)

    \(\partial {\vec {D}_{o}^{t}\left( x_{k}^{t},y_{k}^{t},b_{k}^{t};g \right) } \big /{\partial y=\beta _{1}+}\beta _{2}y_{k}^{t}+{\sum }_{i=1}^2 {\mu _{i}b_{ik}^{t}} +{\sum }_{n=1}^3 {\delta _{n}x_{nk}^{t}} \le 0,\forall k,t.\)

  4. (4)

    \(\partial \vec {D}_{o}^{t}\left( \overline{x},\overline{y} ,\overline{b} ;g \right) \big /{\partial x_{n}=\alpha _{n}+}\alpha _{nn}x_{nk}^{t}+\frac{1}{2}{\sum }_{n'\ne n} {\left( \alpha _{nn'}+\alpha _{n'n} \right) x_{n'k}^{t}} +{\sum }_{i=1}^2 {\eta _{ni}b_{ik}^{t}} +\delta _{n}y_{k}^{t}\ge 0,n=1,2,3\)

  5. (5)

    \(\begin{array}{ll}\partial ^{2}{\vec {D}_{o}^{t}\left( x_{k}^{t},y_{k}^{t},b_{k}^{t};g \right) } \big /{\partial y^{2}=}\beta _{2}\le 0,\forall k,t.\\ \partial ^{2}{\vec {D}_{o}^{t}\left( x_{k}^{t},y_{k}^{t},b_{k}^{t};g \right) } \big /{\partial b_{i}^{2}}=\theta _{ii}\le 0,\forall i,k,t. \end{array}\)

  6. (6)

    \(\partial ^{2}{\vec {D}_{o}^{t}\left( x_{k}^{t},y_{k}^{t},b_{k}^{t};g \right) } \big /{\partial b_{i}\partial y}=\mu _{i}\le 0,\forall i,k,t.\)

  7. (7)

    \(\vec {D}_{o}^{t}\left( x_{k}^{t},y_{k}^{t},0;g \right) <0,\forall k,t\)

  8. (8)

    \(\begin{array}{ll}\beta _{1}g_{y}-{\sum }_{i=1}^2 {\theta _{i}g_{b_{i}}=-1},\beta _{2}g_{y}-{\sum }_{i=1}^2 {\mu _{i}g_{b_{i}}=0},{\mu }_{i}g_{y}-{\sum }_{i^{\prime }=1}^2 {\theta _{ii^{\prime }}g_{b_{i^{\prime }}}=0}\,\,{\mathrm{and}}\\ \delta _{n}g_{y}-{\sum }_{i=1}^2 {\eta _{ni}g_{b_{i}}=0,\forall i,n.} \end{array}\)

  9. (9)

    \(\alpha _{nn'}=\alpha _{n^{\prime }n}\)with \(n,n^{\prime }=1,2,3\) and \(n\ne n^{\prime }\). \(\theta _{ii^{\prime }}=\theta _{i^{\prime }i}\) for \(i,i^{\prime }=1,2\) and \(i\ne i^{\prime }.\)

In this parametric specification we have also imposed through expression (9) cross-output and cross-input symmetry conditions. In Tables 5 and 6 in the “Appendix” we assess the monotonicity conditions, null-jointness property and concavity of the output set frontier.

3.1 Shadow Prices

When pollutants are considered as bad outputs, it is usual to interpret the values of the directional output distance function as a measure of the combined environmental and technical efficiency. The reason for this is that given the level of inputs, the function besides allowing increases in the good output, it also accounts for environmental efficiency as it enables simultaneous decreases in pollutants (see Färe et al. 2005). The directional output distance function approach allows us, however, to not only account for technical and environmental efficiency, but also calculate the shadow prices of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions and the elasticity of substitution between these pollutants. Indeed, since the directional output distance function \(\vec {D}_{o}\left( x,y,b;g \right) \) describes the technology, the revenue function can be written as

$$\begin{aligned} R(x,p,q)={\mathop {{\max }}\limits _{y, b_{1}, b_{2}}}\left\{ py-q_{1}b_{1}-q_{2}b_{2}{:}\,\vec {D}_{o}\left( x,y,b;g \right) \ge 0 \right\} \end{aligned}$$

where \(q=\left( {q_1, q_2 } \right) \) denotes the emissions price vector containing \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) shadow prices, respectively, and p denotes the output price. Chambers et al. (1998) show that the Lagrange multiplier associated with the maximization of revenues corresponds to \(\lambda =pg_y +q_1 g_{b_1 } +q_2 g_{b_2 } \). Hence, the revenue function can be characterized as

$$\begin{aligned} R(x,p,q)={\mathop {{\max }}\limits _{y, b_{1}, b_{2}}}\left\{ py-q_{1}b_{1}-q_{2}b_{2}+\left( pg_{y}+q_{1}g_{b_{1}}+q_{2}g_{b_{2}} \right) \vec {D}_{o}\left( x,y,b;g \right) \right\} . \end{aligned}$$

The corresponding first order conditions with regard to y, \(b_1\) and \(b_2\) are

$$\begin{aligned} \left( {pg_y +q_1 g_{b_1 } +q_2 g_{b_2 } } \right) D_y= & {} -p, \end{aligned}$$
(3)
$$\begin{aligned} \left( {pg_y +q_1 g_{b_1 } +q_2 g_{b_2 } } \right) D_{b_1 }= & {} q_1, \end{aligned}$$
(4)
$$\begin{aligned} \left( {pg_y +q_1 g_{b_1 } +q_2 g_{b_2 } } \right) D_{b_2 }= & {} q_2, \end{aligned}$$
(5)

where \(D_y\) and \(D_{b_i}\) are the first order derivatives of \(\vec {D}_{o}\left( x,y,b;g \right) \) with respect to good output and pollutant \(b_i \), respectively.

The ratio between Eqs. (4) and (5) provides us with the relative shadow price of pollution, which represents the trade-off between these two pollutants, i.e., the shadow marginal rate of transformation.Footnote 11

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{q_1 }{q_2 }=\frac{D_{b_1 } }{D_{b_2 } }\ge 0. \end{aligned}$$
(6)

Moreover, we can obtain the absolute shadow prices of pollution (i.e., the marginal loss in CHP production necessary to reduce \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) or \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions) from the ratio between Eqs. (4) and (3) and (5) and (3):

$$\begin{aligned} q_i =-p\frac{D_{b_i } }{D_y }. \end{aligned}$$
(7)

3.2 Morishima Elasticities of Substitution

The Morishima elasticity of substitution provides us with information on how much the relative shadow prices of outputs will change in response to changes in emission intensities (see Blackorby and Russell 1981, 1989). In the context of the technology described by the directional output distance function, the indirect Morishima elasticity of substitution between pollutants \(b_1 \) and \(b_2 \) can be expressed as (see Kumar and Managi 2011)

$$\begin{aligned} M_{b_1 b_2 } =\frac{\partial \hbox {ln}\left( {q_1 /q_2 } \right) }{\partial \hbox {ln}\left( {b_2 /b_1 } \right) }=b_2^{*}\left( {\frac{D_{b_1 b_2 } }{D_{b_1 } }-\frac{D_{b_2 b_2 }}{D_{b_2 } }} \right) , \end{aligned}$$
(8)

and between pollutant \(b_i \) and good output as

$$\begin{aligned} M_{b_i y} =\frac{\partial \hbox {ln}\left( {q_i /p} \right) }{\partial \hbox {ln}\left( {y/b_i } \right) }=y^{*}\left( {\frac{D_{b_i y} }{D_{b_i } }-\frac{D_{{yy}} }{D_y }} \right) , \end{aligned}$$
(9)

where \(D_{b_1 b_2 }, D_{b_2 b_2 } \), \(D_{b_i y} \), and \(D_{{yy}} \) are second order derivatives of the directional output distance function, \(y^{*}=y\,+\,\vec {D}_{o}\left( x,y,b;g \right) g_{y}\) and \(b_{i}^{*}=b_{i}-\vec {D}_{o}\left( x,y,b;g \right) g_{b_{i}}\). If \(M_{b_1 b_2 } >0\), then \(b_1 \) and \(b_2 \) are Morishima substitutes. That is, the pollutants are substitutes if the emission intensity \((b_2 /b_1)\) increases when the relative shadow price \(\left( {q_2 /q_1 } \right) \) decreases; emission reductions in \(b_1 \) are accompanied by increased emissions in \(b_2\). Conversely, \(b_1 \) and \(b_2\) are complements when \(M_{b_1 b_2}<0\).

Note that \(M_{b_i y} \le 0\) since \(\vec {D}_{o}\left( x,y,b;g \right) \) satisfies monotonicity and concavity properties.Footnote 12 Moreover, in terms of the quadratic directional distance function we can write the elasticity \(M_{b_1 b_2 } \) as

$$\begin{aligned} M_{b_1 b_2 }= & {} b_2^{*}\left( \frac{\theta _{12} }{\theta _1 +\theta _{11} b_{1k}^t +\theta _{12} b_{2k}^t +{\sum }_{n=1}^3 \eta _{n1} x_{{nk}}^t +\mu _1 y_k^t }\right. \nonumber \\&\quad \left. -\,\frac{\theta _{22} }{\theta _2 +\theta _{22} b_{2k}^t +\theta _{21} b_{1k}^t +{\sum }_{n=1}^3 \eta _{n2} x_{{nk}}^t +\mu _2 y_k^t } \right) , \end{aligned}$$
(10)

where the sign of \(M_{b_1 b_2 } =b_2^{*}\left[ {\frac{?}{+}-\frac{-}{+}} \right] \) depends critically on the sign and magnitude of \(\theta _{12} \). In particular, for \(b_2^{*}>0,\) it holds that \(b_1 \) and \(b_2 \) are Morishima substitutes if

  • \(\theta _{12} >0\) or

  • \(\theta _{12} <0\) and \(\left| {\frac{\theta _{12} }{\theta _1 +\theta _{11} b_{1k}^t +\theta _{12} b_{2k}^t +{\sum }_{n=1}^3 \eta _{n1} x_{{nk}}^t +\mu _1 y_k^t }} \right| <\left| {\frac{\theta _{22} }{\theta _2 +\theta _{22} b_{2k}^t +\theta _{21} b_{1k}^t +{\sum }_{n=1}^3 \eta _{n2} x_{{nk}}^t +\mu _2 y_k^t }} \right| \).

By analogy, the elasticity \(M_{b_2 b_1 } \) corresponds to

$$\begin{aligned} M_{b_2 b_1 }= & {} b_1^{*}\left( \frac{\theta _{21} }{\theta _2 +\theta _{22} b_{2k}^t +\theta _{21} b_{1k}^t +{\sum }_{n=1}^3 \eta _{n2} x_{{nk}}^t +\mu _2 y_k^t }\right. \nonumber \\&\qquad \left. -\,\frac{\theta _{11} }{\theta _1 +\theta _{11} b_{1k}^t +\theta _{12} b_{2k}^t +{\sum }_{n=1}^3 \eta _{n1} x_{{nk}}^t +\mu _1 y_k^t } \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(11)

The Morishima elasticities of substitution show that a percentage change in the price ratio \(q_1 /q_2 \) (motivated for instance by an increase in \(q_1 )\) has two effects on the quantity ratio: the first term shows the effect on \(b_1\) while the second term shows the effect on \(b_2 \). Therefore, despite the fact that symmetry conditions for cross-output ensure that \(\theta _{12} =\theta _{21} \), the Morishima elasticities are inherently asymmetric (\(M_{b_1 b_2 } \ne M_{b_2 b_1 } )\) since they represent the difference between two elasticities: a cross elasticity and own price elasticity. In terms of the analysis, the asymmetric substitutability tells us which pollutant is easier to substitute for another pollutant for a fixed amount of output. Note that a lower value of the Morishima elasticities of substitution indicates greater substitution possibilities between pollutants. The intuition behind this is that to generate the same change in the emission intensity (\(b_2 /b_1 )\), a smaller change in the prices \(\left( {q_1 /q_2 } \right) \) is required when the pollutants are close substitutes. Likewise, lower pollution-good output elasticities in absolute value indicate greater substitution possibilities.

We estimate the directional output distance function using a deterministic method, i.e., parametric linear programming (PLP) that allows us to impose parametric restrictions that are a result of the underlying technology such as monotonicity in good or bad outputs. We follow Aigner and Chu’s (1968) procedure of minimizing the sum of the distance between the frontier technology and the actual observations of the generating units in each period. Hence, the method chooses the parameters that make the generating units as efficient as possible subject to a set of restrictions associated with the technology properties already described (see Färe et al. 2001, 2005, 2006).

Note that the choice of directional vector \(g=\left( {g_y, g_{b_1 }, g_{b_2 } } \right) \) affects the magnitude of the first and second order derivatives of the directional distance function through the constraints (8). As in Färe et al. (2006), our choice of directional vector is \(g=({1,1,1})\), i.e., the component of the good output and the components of the two pollutants are equal to one, making the model parsimonious. In Sect. 5.5 we develop a sensitivity analysis estimating the directional distance function in Eq. (2) for two additional direction sets.

We derive estimates of the coefficients for pre- (2001–2004) and post- (2005–2009) EU ETS implementation. We wrote the code to solve the optimization problem in Matlab. In order to avoid convergence problems in the algorithm, all variables are expressed in normalized values, i.e., each output and input is divided by its own sample mean.Footnote 13 Year and firm fixed effects (\(\tau _t \) and \(\varsigma _f )\) are estimated using a set of yearly and firm dummy variables. These variables take the value of one if the observation belongs to year t or firm f, accordingly; and zero otherwise. In the case of the yearly dummies, the reference year corresponds to the first year for each period of analysis (e.g., 2001 for pre-EU ETS and 2005 for post-EU ETS). Regarding the firm dummies, we chose arbitrarily a firm as the reference firm for both periods.Footnote 14 All the dummy variables (except those representing the reference cases) are included in the objective function of the minimization problem to carry out the estimations. Using the estimated coefficients of the directional output distance function, we compute the technical and environmental efficiencies and the Morishima elasticities of substitution between pollutants and between pollutants and output according to Eqs. (8) and (9), respectively. The relative and absolute shadow prices are obtained by applying Eqs. (6) and (7). To identify changes in efficiencies, elasticities, and relative shadow prices before and after the implementation of the EU ETS, we compare the density functions of these measures between periods. To this end, we employ kernel-based methods to statistically test the difference between distributions. Our tests are conducted by computing the nonparametric \(T_{{n}}\)-statistic of Li et al. (2009)Footnote 15 which assesses the equality between two density functions. Let f(x) and g(x) denote the density functions of a random variable x. We test the null hypothesis that \(f(x)=g(x)\) against the alternative hypothesis that \(f(x)\ne g(x)\). Following Hayfield and Racine (2008, 2011), we implement this procedure in the software R with 500 bootstrap repetitions and estimate the \(T_{{n}}\)-statistic using a standard normal kernel. The empirical p values of the consistent density equality test are computed after bootstrapping.

4 Data

Our analysis models production and emissions at the boiler level in the heat and power sector using data for the Swedish CHP plants during 2001–2009. We focus on CHP plants since approximately 75% of the plants in the heat and power sector belong to this group. Moreover, CHP plants have been promoted within the European Union as an effective means to increase the overall energy efficiency (EU Directive 2004/8/EC).Footnote 16 In Sweden approximately 30–50% of the total input energy of a CHP is converted to electricity and the rest to heat (Svensk Fjärrvärme 2011). Though we would have liked to develop the analysis by disaggregating production into heat and power, the information available at the boiler level only allows us to analyze the joint production. Hence, our measure of good output is the amount of useful energy (MWh) commercially sold. This is the sum of electrical energy and process heat in those cases where this heat is sold (generally for district heatingFootnote 17) or used in industrial processes. The two undesirable outputs, \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions, are expressed in metric tons, and as stated above, the inputs consist of installed capacity (MW),Footnote 18 fuel consumption (MWh),Footnote 19 and labor (number of employees). \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions and useful energy are taken from the Swedish Environmental Protection Agency’s (SEPA) \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) charge database. These two variables are measured and reported to the SEPA directly by the generating units along with information about energy fuel shares, installed capacity, and the available \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) combustion and post-combustion technologies (CTs and PCTs, respectively), which makes this dataset unique in the sense that it is the most detailed longitudinal database at the boiler level of the Swedish heat and power sector. Installed capacity is used as a proxy for capital in physical units. With regard to labor, the data at company level were gathered from Retriever Bolagsinfo. For multi-unit plants, we allocated labor to generating units according to their generating capacity ratio.Footnote 20

Although we have \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) values accessed from the SEPA’s EU ETS database, their aggregation at installation level prevents us from recovering the emissions for each boiler. Instead, \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions are estimated based on available data on the boilers’ energy fuel shares and emission factors per fuel type. Hence, we can recover the total input energy that corresponds to the amount of fuel consumed per boiler. In addition, our dataset comprises a wide range of fuel types, i.e., gas, oil, coal, peat, biofuel, and waste. We use emission factors for each fuel classification.Footnote 21 However, this method only considers emissions derived from fuel use for combustion and excludes emissions coming from raw materials,Footnote 22 which—unlike other industries—are not significant in the case of the heat and power generation.Footnote 23

We focus on boilers that operate every year. This group of generating units represents the operation of the sector under normal or standard conditions, i.e., we exclude boilers that may only be switched on under certain circumstances (e.g., as backup during episodes of very cold winters). Two boilers for which information on fuel shares is missing are dropped. One boiler that uses a combination of mixed refinery gas and gas converted during the process is also excluded due to the complexity of the fuel and its extremely high emissions. Finally, our sample consists of a panel of 82 boilers distributed across 35 firms (738 observations, of which 328 are for the period 2001–2004 and 410 are for 2005–2009).

Descriptive statistics of the variables are presented in Table 1. As we can see, there is large variation in emission rates among boilers. \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emission rates vary from zero to 428.5 tons/GWh, while \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emission rates vary almost 20-fold from 0.03 to 0.68 tons/GWh. This reflects differences within the sector in fuel mix, fuel usage, boiler size, and availability of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) abatement technologies.

Table 1 Descriptive statistics

5 Results

In this section, we describe and analyze the results of our estimates of technical efficiencies, elasticities of substitution, and shadow prices.

5.1 Technical Efficiency and Technical Progress

The estimated coefficients of the quadratic directional output distance function are shown in Table 2, and Tables 5 and 6 in the “Appendix” verify that the coefficients are consistent with monotonicity, concavity, and null-jointness constraints.

Table 2 Parameter estimates of the quadratic directional output distance function using the parametric linear programming approach \((g=1,1,1)\)

Stringent environmental regulations have a positive effect not only on environmental quality but also possibly on firms’ absolute performance if they induce development of new technologies and a more efficient use of resources. Compliance costs due to stricter environmental regulations make environmentally friendlier technological development relatively less costly. This should be represented by an outward shift of the production possibility curve or an inward shift in the input coefficient space, which means that with a given set of resources it is now possible to produce more goods and services without worsening the environmental quality (Xepapadeas and Zeeuw 1999).

Our results from the Swedish CHP plants are a case in point and indicate the existence of significant technical progress. We compute the frontier for the years 2001 and 2009 (the initial and final years in our sample) using our PLP coefficient estimates. The frontiers are obtained for a generating unit using the mean values of inputs in both periods. The normalized values of inputs of this generating unit are substituted into the directional output distance function leading to an expression that only depends on the good and bad outputs. We solve this equation for values of the good output that make the directional output distance function equal to zero (i.e., no technical inefficiency). The frontiers are plotted allowing for a grid of values of both pollutants. As shown in Fig. 2, technological progress drives a significant movement of the frontier towards reduced emissions of both pollutants, though as expected the overall reduction is biased towards \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emission reduction. The movement of the frontier itself is consistent with the fact that the amount of heat and power generation per unit of emissions increases for both pollutants between periods, but the efficiency increase is greater in the case of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\). We could thus say that the technical change is “carbon saving” in much the same way as traditionally technical changes often have been characterized as “labor saving.”Footnote 24 On average, \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions per GWh by CHP plants decreased by 15% between the periods (from 81.4 in 2001–2004 to 69.7 ton/GWh in 2005–2009) and by approximately 5% for \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) (from 0.245 to 0.232 ton/GWh).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Frontiers in 2001 and 2009. Note The frontiers are obtained for a generating unit using the mean values of inputs in both periods. The normalized values of inputs of this generating unit are substituted into the directional output distance function leading to an expression that only depends on the good and bad outputs. The plots are expressed in original units multiplying the normalized values by the corresponding means of good and bad outputs

Thus far we have analyzed technical progress at the frontier. We are also interested in the performance of all firms, which is conveniently measured by studying technical efficiency relative to each respective frontier: We find that out of 82 boilers of the sample, 45 were found to operate at least once on the frontier during 2001–2004 and 44 at least once on the frontier during 2005–2009. Thirty-three boilers were found to operate on the frontier at least one of the years in each of the two periods.

The estimations of technical and environmental efficiency yield mean inefficiency values of 14.86 and 17.68% for the pre- and post-introduction periods of the EU ETS, respectively.Footnote 25 This indicates that during 2001–2004, boilers on average could have expanded heat and power generation by 35.56 GWh (i.e., 239.3 \(\times \) 14.86%) and contracted \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions by 3730 tons (25,098 \(\times \) 14.86%) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions by 6.94 tons (46.7 \(\times \) 14.86%) if they would have adopted the best practice of frontier-generating units. Similarly, in 2005–2009 boilers on average could have increased their production by 42.91 GWh and decreased \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions by 3638 and 7.51 tons, respectively, if the generating units were to operate efficiently.Footnote 26 Given these results, the amount of possible reduction in emissions and increase in heat and power generation that could have been achieved between periods following the practice of the most efficient generating units is of considerable magnitude. The bootstrapped Li et al. (2009) \(T_{\mathrm{n}}\)-statistic allows us to compare the inefficiency distributions between periods and conclude that the boilers are statistically equally efficient in the two periods at the 10% significance level.

If we compare inefficiencies by fuel type, we find that the highest technical and environmental efficiencies are reached by boilers using mainly biofuel while the highest inefficiencies are found for boilers burning mainly fossil fuels. For instance, average inefficiencies for boilers with biofuel shares exceeding 80% are 9.64% for 2001–2004 and 13.60% for 2005–2009 whereas the corresponding numbers for boilers with fossil fuel shares exceeding 80% are 36.37 and 33.42%, respectively. In the case of fossil fuels, the bootstrapped Li et al. (2009) test indicates that the differences between periods are not statistically significant, while in the case of biofuels the test indicates that inefficiencies tend to increase in the period 2005–2009 (p value \(=\) 0.056).

When it comes to the availability of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) abatement technologies, we find that the inefficiencies are larger for boilers that use only PCTs (22.27% in 2001–2004 vs. 27.37% in 2005–2009) compared with boilers that use only CTs (11.11% in 2001–2004 vs. 15.21% in 2005–2009). As discussed in Sect. 2, PCTs usually require energy that might lead to increased \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions. Nevertheless, as shown in Table 3, we find a significant correlation between the type of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) technology installed and the boiler size. Indeed, if we classify boilers according to size, we observe that the incidence of CTs (whose investment cost is lower) is greater among small boilers compared with PCTs, which are more expensive and mostly adopted by large boilers (alone or in combination with CTs).Footnote 27 The incidence of biofuel use is also greater among small boilers. Moreover, these boilers tend to minimize the use of fossil fuels to the largest possible extent by using alternative fuels such as peat and waste, which were exempt from \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) taxation at certain times during the period 2001–2009. Overall, these findings suggest that smaller boilers substitute pollutants by means of the choice of fuel while larger boilers substitute by adopting \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\)-reducing technologies, which is a reflection of the fact that the production process of large boilers is relatively more inflexible and—as discussed in the following section—less sensitive to variations in the relative price of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\).

Table 3 \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions, fuel use, and availability of abatement technology by boiler size
Fig. 3
figure 3

a Kernel distribution of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)-output elasticities. b kernel distribution of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\)-output elasticities. Note Elasticities lower than −8.5 are not shown for convenience of presentation

5.2 Output-\(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and Output-\(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) Elasticities

With regard to the pollution-good output elasticities, Fig. 3a, b illustrate the kernel distributions between the two periods (and report the mean values, standard deviation, and p-value of the nonparametric test). As expected, the pollution-good output elasticities are negative, implying that the emission intensity decreases when the relative shadow price of emissions to output increases. When it comes to \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\), the mean \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)-output elasticity changed from −0.420 to −0.176 between the periods. That is, substitution increased since lower pollution-good output elasticities in absolute values indicate greater substitution possibilities. Using the Li et al. (2009) test, we are able to reject the null hypothesis of equality between the density functions of the pollution-good output elasticities pre- and post-introduction of the EU ETS for \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\). An explanation for the increased substitution is technological development. Indeed, the results in the previous section indicate that several technical measures were implemented in order to reduce \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions. The trend towards phasing out of fossil fuels in Sweden has been quite stable over the sampled period and most firms in the sector have already switched to “carbon-free” fuels. For instance, during the period 2005–2009 the fraction of boilers with biofuel shares greater than or equal to 80% was approximately 63%, while the fraction of boilers using mainly fossil fuels was around 11% (see Table 3). As discussed before, there are clear differences between small and large boilers; the Morishima elasticities of substitution indicate greater substitution among small boilers (e.g., a \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)-output elasticity of −0.243 and −0.076 for the first and second period versus −0.634 and −0.309 for large boilers). Consequently, the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emission intensity of small boilers is lower than that of large boilers.

The mean absolute value of the \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\)-output elasticity also decreased between the pre- and post-EU ETS periods (from −1.823 to −0.676), indicating greater substitution. The test that compares the density functions of the elasticities before and after the introduction of the EU ETS indicates that there is a statistically significant difference between the two distributions at the 1% significance level. This result might be explained by the fact that the fraction of generating units without any \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) abatement measure declined between the periods from 21 to 17% and also that the simultaneous adoption of more than one \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) reduction technology increased from 19 to 27% (see Table 3). The decrease in absolute value of these elasticities for the period 2005–2009 would suggest that the easiest emission reductions have already been undertaken. Therefore further reductions of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) per unit of output will only be supported by much higher charges for \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions. \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emission reductions have certainly been achieved since the \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) charge was implemented yet the slow pace of these reductions relative to \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) during the last decade also reflects an inclination to rather favor \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) than \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emission reductions.

When it comes to \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\)-output elasticity by size, our results indicate greater substitution among small boilers than among large boilers. For small boilers, the \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\)-output elasticity is −0.564 and −0.360 for the first and second period, respectively, versus −3.348 and −1.100 for large boilers.

Fig. 4
figure 4

a Kernel distribution of \(\mathrm{CO}_{2}\)\(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) elasticities. Note Elasticities greater than 6 are not shown for convenience of presentation, b kernel distribution of elasticities \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\)\(\hbox {CO}_{2}\). Note Elasticities greater than 0.6 are not shown for convenience of presentation

5.3 \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)\(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) Substitution

One main purpose of this study is to assess the existence of substitutability between \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\). Our results indicate that \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) are substitutes. Like in the case of pollution-good output elasticities, lower absolute values of the Morishima elasticities of substitution indicate greater substitution possibilities between pollutants. Hence, substitution increased during the period 2005–2009. For instance, the mean estimates of the Morishima \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)\(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) elasticity correspond to 1.706 for 2001–2004 and 0.472 for 2005–2009. The mean estimates of the corresponding \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\)\(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) elasticity are 0.446 for 2001–2004 and 0.004 for 2005–2009.

The asymmetry of the elasticities indicates that it is easier to substitute \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) with \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) than \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) with \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\). In other words, firms are much more sensitive to variations in \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) prices and therefore more willing to decrease \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions at the expense of increasing \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions rather than the other way around. Clearly, this is linked to the fact that \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions have a much higher opportunity cost than \(\hbox {NO}_{x}\) emissions. As mentioned before, a policy implication that could be derived from here is that—given the high opportunity costs of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions—the \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) fee would have to be increased to a higher level than its current value in order to achieve large \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emission reductions. An alternative implication has to do with the choice of policy instruments as the effects of climate policy on \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions depend crucially on the environmental regulation of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\). In particular, \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions change in response to climate policy since \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) is subject to price regulation. If \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) instead would be subject to, for instance, an emissions cap-and-trade system, then climate policy would not change \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions but would change the price of permits in the \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) market.

Kernel distributions of the elasticities between pollutants are depicted in Fig. 4a, b. Using the bootstrapped Li et al. (2009) \(T_{{n}}\)-statistics, we tested the null hypothesis of equal density functions between the pre- and post-implementation period of the EU ETS. We reject this null hypothesis; the elasticity of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)\(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) substitution does tend to shift towards the left-hand side of the distribution, indicating greater substitution in 2005–2009 than in 2001–2004. In the case of the \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\)\(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) elasticity, we also observe that for many generating units the estimates are concentrated around zero. Further \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)\(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) substitution has increased because most firms have implemented technical measures to allow for this substitution to take place (they have in fact undertaken a complete transition to biofuels).

The asymmetric substitution is also observed when classifying by boiler size. Among small boilers, it is easier to substitute \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) for \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) than \(\hbox {CO}_{2 }\) for \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\), e.g., the value of the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)\(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) elasticity for small boilers is 0.699 and 0.340 for the first and second period, respectively, versus 0.172 and 0.001 for the \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\)\(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) elasticity. Similar evidence is found for large boilers; the value of the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)\(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) elasticity is 2.926 and 0.648 for the first and second period versus 0.777 and 0.008 for the \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\)\(\hbox {CO}_{2 }\)elasticity. Moreover, in line with the results described in the previous section, in the case of both the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)\(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) and the \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\)\(\hbox {CO}_{2 }\) elasticity, we observe that substitution is greater among small boilers than large boilers, which might be explained by a more inflexible production process for large boilers.

5.4 Shadow Prices

Finally, we compute the absolute and relative shadow prices. When it comes to the absolute shadow prices, we follow Färe et al.’s (2005) approach and assume that the price of heat and power is known (and equal to its shadow price). We proxy the price of heat and power through the annual price of district heating reported by the Swedish Energy Agency. The average price corresponds to 56.6 €/MWh for the period 2001–2004 and 61.7 €/MWh for the period 2005–2009.Footnote 28 Based on our estimates of the derivatives \(D_y \) and \(D_{b_i } \), the shadow prices of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) for the period 2001–2004 correspond to 5.33 and 80,136 €/ton, respectively. The shadow prices for the period 2005–2009 are significantly higher (which supports the claim that the easiest emission reductions have already been undertaken) at 19.23 and 129,556 €/ton, respectively. Furthermore, there is a very small (though statistically significant) increase in the shadow price of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) from a mean of 0.00018 in 2001–2004 to a mean of 0.00019 in 2005–2009Footnote 29 (Fig. 5.).

The sum of the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) tax (net of deductions) plus the EU ETS price corresponded to 52 €/ton in 2001–2004 and 33.4 €/ton in 2005–2009. The price of the \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) charge corresponded to 3766.5 and 4143.1 €/ton, respectively. Hence, in terms of €/ton, the regulatory relative prices of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) decreased from a mean of 0.014 to a mean of 0.008. Overall, these estimates suggest that, in relative terms, the relative shadow price of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions is lower than the regulatory relative price. The comparison of absolute prices indicates that with regard to the prices of the regulations, \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) has been cheaper to reduce while the reverse holds for \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\). This is consistent with our previous claim that in order to achieve further \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) reductions, the \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) fee has to be increased to a greater extent.

5.5 The Choice of the Directional Vector

One important advantage of the directional distance function is the possibility to analyze efficiency by increasing good outputs while simultaneously decreasing bad outputs. However, the wide range of possible directions allows for a great deal of subjectivity regarding the importance of the production of the good output and the abatement of bad output. So far we have assumed that pollution reduction is regarded as an equally important target as the increase of good output. Moreover, we assume that \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) abatement is regarded as equally important as \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) abatement. Nevertheless, as discussed by Agee et al. (2014), increasing output might be regarded as more important than reducing emissions. Furthermore, in line with the discussion in Sect. 2, since the transition to a carbon-free economy is as key environmental goal of the Swedish government, it is reasonable to assume that \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) abatement is regarded as more important than \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) abatement. Hence, in this section, we develop a sensitivity analysis estimating the elasticities of substitution and efficiency for two additional direction sets, namely (1.2, 1, 1) and (1, 1, 0.8).Footnote 30 The first vector represents the case where the increase in good output is 20% more important than a decrease in pollution and the second represents the case where reducing \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions is as important as increasing output and 25% more important than a decrease in \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Kernel distribution of relative shadow prices of \(\hbox {CO}_{2} /\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\), Note Relative shadow price estimates greater than 0.0032 are not shown for convenience of presentation

Table 4 Sensitiveness to the directional vector

Table 4 shows that our results are generally robust to the choice of the direction vector. For instance, \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) are substitutes regardless of the directional vector and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\)\(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) substitution increases post-EU ETS implementation. Moreover, when it comes to inefficiency, the differences between periods remain statistically insignificant, though (interestingly) the level of the inefficiencies tend to be lower when there is a greater focus on good output instead of pollution, i.e., the directional vector (1.2, 1, 1) instead of vectors (1, 1, 1) and (1, 1, 0.8).

The magnitude of the absolute shadow prices of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) for the period 2005–2009 tends to be lower under vectors (1.2, 1, 1) and (1, 1, 0.8) than under vector (1, 1, 1). Regarding relative prices, under the directional vector (1, 1, 0.8), the relative shadow price of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) is statistically lower for the period 2005–2009 than for the period 2001–2004. Note that for this vector, \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) abatement is less important than \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) abatement. The reduction in the relative shadow price is consistent with the reduction in the relative price of the regulation. As a robustness check we also estimated the shadow prices and elasticities of substitution for the same set of directional vectors using stochastic frontier analysis (SFA) and corrected ordinary least squares (COLS). In line with the PLP results, SFA and COLS showed that \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) are substitutes. The results are not qualitatively sensitive to the estimation technique, however for observations satisfying technology properties SFA and COLS yielded higher elasticities and shadow prices (in absolute values) than the PLP method (Du et al. 2015a also found similar results for SFA). A disadvantage of the SFA and COLS methods is that around 74–79% of the observations simultaneously violated monotonicity in good and undesirable outputs. In contrast, our PLP results fully satisfy the properties of the underlying technology through the sample. Finally, for comparison purposes we also estimated inefficiencies using DEA. The inefficiencies were much lower in magnitude than those obtained with PLP, indicating that the output set of the quadratic specification contains the piecewise linear DEA output possibility set (see Färe et al. 2005).Footnote 31

6 Synergies and Trade-Offs Between Reductions of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) Emissions

Has the overlapping of climate policies brought about increased \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions? Since pollutants are substitutes, we do find a tendency in this direction. However, \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions have not actually increased in practice as technological development has led to reduced emissions of both pollutants. Furthermore, contrary to what one may have expected, the regulatory relative price of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions has decreased since harmonization with the EU actually implied a sizeable fall in the price of carbon emissions for most CHP plants in addition to the simultaneous increase in the local \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) charge in 2008. This is to say that in relative terms, \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) policies in Sweden have become less stringent after the introduction of the EU ETS due to the variations in the levels of the local policies. A natural question that arises is what would have happened if the carbon tax had not been phased out. In such a case, the regulatory relative price (\(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}})\) per ton during the period 2005–2009 would have been 2.625 times higher (i.e., 0.029 instead of 0.008). Based on our estimates for the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)\(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) elasticity for the period 2001–2004, we calculate that the (\(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}/\hbox {CO}_{2})\) emissions intensity would have increased from 0.186% in 2001–2004 to 0.520% in 2005–2009. In reality, however, it increased to a much lower extent than predicted (i.e., 0.207%) due to the combined effect of technological progress and the fact that the regulatory relative price of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) decreased sharply.

As mentioned in the introduction, some previous studies have found ancillary benefits from reductions in greenhouse gases in the U.S. For instance, Burtraw et al. (2003) simulate the effects of moderate carbon taxes for electricity production on reductions of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions beyond the requirements of the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments. Their results indicate that health-related ancillary benefits appear significant relative to the costs of those reductions and that they should play an important role in facilitating the debate regarding near-term policies to address the threat of climate change. Similar evidence is provided by Agee et al. (2014), who report that the marginal effect of reducing \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) on \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions is positive, roughly of equal absolute magnitude, and explained by adoption of more efficient production and pollution control technologies.

How do we reconcile their findings with the findings of our study? We believe that the differences are explained by several factors, including significant differences in emission intensity as well as in the type and stringency of the regulations in place. For instance, information provided by Mekaroonreung and Johnson (2012) for a sample of 336 U.S. bituminous coal-burning electricity plants over the period 2000–2008 indicates that the average \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions were 922.56 and 1.790 tons/GWh, respectively. By contrast, the average \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emission intensities in our sample were 74.87 and 0.238 tons/GWh. As discussed in Sect. 2, the low emission intensity of Swedish CHP plants is the result of very ambitious national policies with extremely high stringency levels compared with those in the U.S. Stringent policies have yielded significant reductions in emissions, putting Swedish plants in a situation where there is no slack or low-hanging fruit that will increase general efficiency and thus cut emissions of both pollutants. Instead, as indicated by our results, if further \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emission reductions are to be achieved we would expect hard tradeoffs in the form of increases in \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emission intensities. Finally, there is a difference when it comes to the type of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) regulations in place. In the U.S., \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) regulations generally take the form of tradable permits while Sweden has chosen to control \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions through a refundable fee. As shown by Ambec and Coria (2013), under price regulation firms modify their abatement levels of both pollutants in response to an increased stringency of climate policy, while if \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) were regulated through quantity regulations we would only observe an increase in the marginal cost of reducing \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) without any effects on the level of emissions.

7 Conclusions

The implementation of environmental policies to reduce greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions does not only have a global impact, but can also bring local co-benefits (or costs) by reducing (increasing) other air pollutants due to complementarity or substitution. These interactions have clear implications for policy design as many European countries are committed to reach the Kyoto obligations and there are currently multiple policies in place aiming to reduce \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions. The question is what ancillary benefits (costs) we can expect from pursuing GHG reduction policies and local air pollution policies simultaneously. We explore this question formally by analyzing the patterns of substitution between \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) in the heat and power sector in Sweden induced by the interaction of national and international environmental policies.

We model the pollution technology of generating units in the Swedish heat and power sector as a non-separable production process where \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\), \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\), and production are treated as joint outputs. We use a directional output distance function that accounts for the simultaneous expansion of good outputs and contraction of bad outputs, which is a fair representation of the problem that many regulated firms deal with. We choose a quadratic representation of the technology and subsequently derive the estimates of elasticities between \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) and heat and power generation. Through this method, we characterize changes in the relative performance of Swedish combined heat and power (CHP) plants with respect to \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions in response to variations in the level of stringency of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) policies and multiple layers of regulation. To evaluate the change in elasticities or relative shadow prices, we compare the probability distributions between the periods 2001–2004 (pre-introduction of the EU ETS) and 2005–2009 (post-introduction) by means of a kernel consistent density test.

Our results indicate that there are important interactions between the abatement efforts for \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\). Indeed, we find that in the combined heat and power generation sector, \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) and \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) are substitutes, implying that regulatory efforts that limit emissions of one pollutant might have the unintended consequence of increasing the other pollutant. Overall, the degree of substitution for CHP plants between these two pollutants increases after the introduction of the EU ETS in response to technological development and regulatory changes that led to a reduced relative price of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}/\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\).

Our results also indicate that \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) is more sensitive than \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) to prices, which means that if the regulator is to encourage a large reduction in \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions, the charge must be increased to a much higher level than the present. This is also confirmed by our estimates of the shadow price of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\), which is much higher than the current value of the \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) fee. It is also consistent with the fact that technological development has been biased towards \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emission reductions, implying that it has become easier to reduce \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions than \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions per unit of output.

Finally, our results are robust to choice of directional vectors. The fact that generating units respond to variation in the relative prices of emissions by changing the intensity of their abatement efforts suggests that there is a need for policy coordination to avoid unintended effects of one policy instrument on the emissions of other pollutants. This is particularly important if abatement of climate and local air pollutants are substitutes since the unintended costs of climate policy in the form of local pollution can make it less acceptable to the public and policymakers. This is an area where much research is needed since we are experiencing a polycentric approach to climate change with mitigation and adaptation activities undertaken by multiple policy actors at a range of different levels. Furthermore, a caveat of our analysis is that our dataset only includes generating units of the heat and power sector. Nevertheless, different industrial sectors might differ significantly in terms of the relative burden of local and global air pollution regulations. Thus, even though the analysis of the variations in technical complementarity/substitutability across industries is beyond the scope of the study it is suggested as a relevant area for further research.