Skip to main content
Log in

Can Defaults Save the Climate? Evidence from a Field Experiment on Carbon Offsetting Programs

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Individual preferences for environmental policies can be influenced by the frame in which choices and decisions are presented. In this paper we present results of a field experiment on the contributions to carbon offsetting programs under two alternative treatments for the default option. The opt-in treatment asked subjects to pay for the policy proposal while the opt-out treatment asked subjects if they wanted to be excluded from payment for the policy proposal. The results show that the frame of the default option had a significant effect on the amount of money paid for the policy proposal. Subjects were more likely to accept the policy proposal if the default option was the opt-out treatment. The results have implications for the design of environmental policies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In practice, the efforts of companies to offer customers the option of paying to offset environmental costs do not have the same success in real markets (BBC 2007). For instance, Gössling and Schumacher (2010) found that only 5 % respondents claimed to have offset their flight (Gössling et al. 2007). Thus, hypothetical stated preference surveys may not approximate real market results, leading to “hypothetical bias” or “intentions versus actions bias”.

  2. For a review of previous applications of field experiments and its properties to implement robust empirical tests outside the lab see Harrison and List (2004). This methodology collects data in the least obtrusive way while still maintaining the necessary control to execute a clean comparison between samples (List 2003). This highlights the naturalness and realism of human decision-making.

  3. There are a number of companies offering consumers the chance to contribute through voluntary carbon offsetting payments. Gössling et al. (2007) found out that there are relevant differences in the approaches that these organizations use in the calculations of emissions, compensation measures, prices, company structures and evaluation processes. The authors conclude that atmosfair “seems to use a scientifically sound and holistic approach to compensation”.

  4. A Referee to this paper raised concern about the unspecified amount of \(\text{ CO}_{2}\) impacts in the valuation scenario posed to potential travellers. In focus groups, we tried various scenarios in which subjects were presented with the actual amounts of \(\text{ CO}_{2}\) emissions caused by their air flight trip. However, we found that this complication was unnecessary since subjects were not concerned with the actual amount emitted by their flight but with a policy to offset the amount actually emitted. That is, subjects were found to be insensitive to the amount of damage caused by their own flight. On the other hand, as we referred earlier the amount of \(\text{ CO}_{2}\) emissions varies according to the calculations made by different organizations and institutions. In addition, we also found that there was not great variability in emissions for potential visitors coming by air from Europe to the Canary Islands.

  5. Note that if the subject decides to buy the offset option, the disutility for generating CO2 and the cost of generating the beliefs about the right amount of consumption disappear. That is, \(\text{ D}(\text{ X}-\text{ Y})=\text{ C}(\text{ Y})=0\)

  6. Some previous examples of how misleading can be standard parametric approaches in estimating welfare analysis using stated preference data are Kriström (1990), Araña and León (2005), (2006); Araña and León (2007) and Watanabe (2011), for single bounded dichotomous choice data. For examples in the mainstream statistics literature see Yatchew and Griliches (1984) or Horowitz (1993).

  7. For a very intuitive and non-technical description of the methodology see Carson et al. (2004, appendix F, section 2, pp. 171–176). For a formal mathematical derivation of the mean and variance WTP estimator see Hanemann and Kanninen (1999) or Carson et al. (2004, app. F, section 4, pp. 178–183).

  8. The lower bound mean WTP can be estimated by multiplying the lower bound of each interval by the fraction of sample estimated to lie in each interval and summing the resulting column of numbers. For instance, E(WTP_Opt-OUT) = (0*0.19) +  (10*0.17) + (20*0.19) + (40*0.07) + (60*0.38) = 31.29. In order to calculate the interval confidence for the lower bound mean WTP one needs to incorporate additional assumptions about the nature of the latent WTP distribution. Here we employ the conventional assumptions of normal distribution and calculate a 95 % bootstrap-based confidence interval using the percentile method (Effron and Tibshirani 1993).

  9. An alternative way to include covariates and maintaining a Turnbull-type approach is to impose a parametric structure to the link function that relates the dependent variable and its predictors. Some early examples in labor economics are Heckman and Singer (1984) and Araña and León (2005) in the context of contingent valuation. A competitive alternative is to adopt a Bayesian non-parametric approach, which uses a flexible mixture of distributions as a link function. This approach allows researchers to maintain the flexibility of a non-parametric model, incorporating covariates and accounting for preferences heterogeneity at the same time. Some recent examples are Geweke (forthcoming) in the context of choice experiments and León and Araña (2012) in the context of environmental valuation. Following reviewers’ recommendation and since the nature of the field experiment did not allow us to have a large list of potential covariates and main results were not sensitive to the econometric approach adopted, a simple Turnbull and probit analysis are presented for this specific application.

  10. This result can be interpreted as supporting the idea of arbitrary anchoring effects (e.g. Ariely et al. 2003; Bateman et al. 2008).

References

  • Akter S, Brouwer R, Brander L, van Beukering P (2009) Respondent uncertainty in a contingent market for carbon offsets. Ecol Econ 68(6):1858–1863

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Araña JE, León CJ (2006) Modelling unobserved heterogeneity in contingent valuation of health risks. Appl Econ 38(19):2315–2325

    Google Scholar 

  • Araña JE, León CJ (2007) Repeated dichotomous choice formats for elicitation of willingness to pay: Simultaneous estimation and anchoring effect. Environ Resour Econ 36(4), 475–497

    Google Scholar 

  • Araña JE, León CJ (2008) Do emotions matter? Coherent preferences under anchoring and emotional effects. Ecol Econ 66(4):700–711

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Araña JE, León CJ, Hanemann WM (2008) Emotions and decision rules in discrete choice experiments for valuing health care programmes for the elderly. J Health Econ 27(3):753–769

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Araña JE, León CJ (2005) Flexible mixture distribution modeling of dichotomous choice contingent valuation with heterogeneity. J Environ Econ Manag 50:170–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Araña JE, León CJ (2012) Scale perception bias in the valuation of environmental risks. Appl Econ 44:2607–2617

    Google Scholar 

  • Araña JE, León CJ, Sergio Moreno-Gil, Zubiaurre AR (2013) A comparison of tourists’ valuation of climate change policy using different pricing frames. J Travel Res doi:10.1177/0047287512457260

  • Ariely D, Loewenstein G, Prelec D (2003) “Coherent arbitrariness”: stable demand curves without stable preferences. Q J Econ 118:73–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ayer M, Brunk HD, Ewing GM, Reid WT, Silverman E (1955) An empirical distribution function for sampling with incomplete information. Ann Math Stat 26:641–647

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bateman I, Burgess D, Hutchinson G, Matthews D (2008) Learning design contingent valuation (LDCV): NOAA guidelines, preference learning and coherent arbitrariness. J Environ Econ Manag 55:127–141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • BBC (2007) Global public opinion survey on climate change. Web reference (10/12/2007): http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/shared/bsp/hi/pdfs/02_11_07bbcclimatesurvey.pdf

  • Beshears J, Choi JJ, Laibson D, Madrian BC (2008) How are preferences revealed? J Public Econ 92(8):1787–1794

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biswas D (2009) The effects of option framing on consumer choices: making decisiosn in rational versus experiential processing modes. J Consum Behav 8(5):284–299

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer C, Issacharoff S, Loewenstein G, O’Donoghue T, Rabin M (2003) Regulation for conservatives: behavioral economics and the case for ‘Asymmetric Paternalism’. Univ Pa Law Rev 151(3):101–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carson RT, Conaway MB, Hanemann WM, Krosnick JA, Mitchell RC, Presser S (2004) Valuing oil spill prevention: a case study of california’s central coast. Kluwer, Dordrecht

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlsson F (2010) Design of stated preference surveys: Is there more to learn from behavioral economics? Environ Res Econ 46:167–177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper JC (1993) Optimal bid selection for dichotomous choice contingent valuation surveys. J Environ Econ Manag 24(1):25–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DellaVigna S (2009) Psychology and economics: evidence from the field. J Econ Lit 47:315–372

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Effron B, Tibshirani RBJ (1993) An introduction to the bootstrap. Chapman and Hall, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Geweke J (forthcoming) Nonparametric Bayesian modelling of monotone preferences for discrete choice experiments. J Econom, forthcoming

  • Gössling S, Schumacher KP (2010) Implementing carbon neutral destination policies: issues from the Seychelles. J Sustain Tour 18(3):377–391

    Google Scholar 

  • Gössling S, Paul Upham JB, Ceron JP, Dubois G, Peeters P, Stradas W (2007) Voluntary carbon offsetting schemes for aviation: efficiency, credibility and sustainable tourism. J Sustain Tour 15(3)

  • Gowdy JM (2008) Behavioral economics and climate change policy. J Econ Behav Organ 68(3–4):632–644

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanemann WM, Kanninen B (1999) The statistical analysis of discrete-response CV data. In: Bateman IJ, Willis KG (eds) Valuing environmental preferences: theory and practice of the contingent valuation method in the US, EU and developing countries. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrison GW, List JA (2004) Field experiments. J Econ Lit 42(4):1009–1055

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J, Singer B (1984) A method of minimizing the impact of distributional assumptions in econometric models for duration data. Econometrica 52:271–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horowitz JL (1993) Semiparametric and nonparametric estimation of quantal response model. In: Maddala GS, Rao CR, Vinod HD (eds) Handbook of statistics, vol 11. Elsevier Science Publisher, BV, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson Eric, Goldstein Daniel (2003) Do defaults save lives? Science 302:39–1338

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson EJ, Steffel M, Goldstein D (2005) Making better decisions: from measuring to constructing preferences. Health Psychol 24(4):817–822

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D (2003) Maps of bounded rationality: psychology for behavioral economics. Am Econ Rev 93:1449–1475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Miller DT (1986) Norm theory: comparing reality to its alternatives. Psychol Rev 93:136–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan EL, Meier P (1958) Nonparametric estimation from incomplete observations. J Am Stat Assoc 53(282):457–481

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King G, Murray CJL, Salomon JA, Tandon A (2004) Enhancing the validity of cross-cultural comparability of measurement in survey research. Am J Political Sci Rev 98(1):191–207

    Google Scholar 

  • Kriström B (1990) A non-parametric approach to the estimation of welfare measures in discrete response valuation studies. Land Econ

  • Kriström B (1993) Comparing continuous and discrete contingent valuation questions. Environ Res Econ

  • León CJ, Araña JE (2012) The dynamics of preference elicitation after an environmental disaster: stability and emotional load. Land Econ 88(2):362–381

    Google Scholar 

  • León CJ, Araña JE, de Leon J (2013a) Valuing the social cost of corruption using subjective well being data (SWB) and the technique of vignettes. Appl Econ 45(27):3863–3870

    Google Scholar 

  • León CJ, Araña JE, de Leon J (2013b) Correcting for scale perception bias in measuring corruption: an application to chile and spain. Soc Indic Res doi:10.1007/s11205-012-0185-7

  • Levin IP, Gaeth GJ (1988) Framing of attribute information before and after consuming the product. J Consumer Res 15:374–378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levin IP, Schneider SL, Gaeth GJ (1998) All frames are not created equal: a typology and critical analysis of framing effects. Organ Behav Human Decis Process 76:149–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List JA (2003) Does market experience eliminate market anomalies? Q J Econ 118(1):41–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein G, Haisley E (2008) The economist as therapist: methodological issues raised by “light” paternalism. In: Caplin A, Schotter A (eds) Foundations of positive and normative economics, vol 1 in the handbook of economic methodologies. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Löfgren A, Martinsson P, Hennlock M, Sterner T (2012) Are experienced people affected by a pre-set default option—Results from a field experiment. J Environ Econ Manag 63(1):66–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marteau TM (1980) Framing of information: its influence upon decisions of doctors and patients. Br J Social Psychol 28:89–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacKerron GJ, Egerton C, Gaskell C, Parpia A, Mourato S (2009) Willingness to pay for carbon offset certification and co-benefits among (high-)flying young adults in the UK. Energy Policy 37:1372–1381

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McNeil BJ, Pauker SG, Sox HC, Tversky A (1982) On the elicitation of preferences for alternative therapies. New Engl J Med 306:1259–1262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rabin M (1994) Cognitive dissonance and social change. J Econ Behav Organ 23(2):177–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shogren J, Parkhurst G, Banerjee P (2010) Two cheers and a qualm for behavioral environmental economics. Environ Res Econ 46(2):235–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler RH, Sunstein C (2003) Libertarian paternalism. Am Econ Rev Am Econ Assoc 93(2):175–179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler RH, Sunstein CR (2008) Nudge: improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Watanabe M (2011) Nonparametric estimation of mean willingness to pay from discrete response valuation data. Am J Agric Econ 92(4):1114–1135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson DK, Kaplan RM, Schneiderman LJ (1987) Framing of decisions and selections of alternatives in health care. Social Behav 2:51–59

    Google Scholar 

  • Witt U (2010) Symbolic consumption and the social construction of product characteristics. Struct Change Econ Dyn 21:17–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yatchew A, Griliches Z (1984) Specification error in probit models. Rev Econ Stat 66:134–139

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors greatly acknowledge financial support by the projects VEM2004-08558 and ECO2009-12629 of the Spanish Ministry of Education and project 200801000381 of the Agencia Canaria de Investigación (ACIISI). Useful comments and discussion with W. Michael Hanemann, Jordan Louviere, Bart Frischknecht helped to improve the piece. This paper was finished while Carmelo León was visiting the Center for the Study of Choice (CenSoc) at University of Technology of Sydney. Acknowledgment for access to an excellent and inspiring working environment is also recognized. Only the authors are responsible for the opinions expressed and potential errors in the content.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jorge E. Araña.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Araña, J.E., León, C.J. Can Defaults Save the Climate? Evidence from a Field Experiment on Carbon Offsetting Programs. Environ Resource Econ 54, 613–626 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-012-9615-x

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-012-9615-x

Keywords

Navigation