Skip to main content
Log in

Agriculture-Nutrition Linkages, Cooking-Time, Intrahousehold Equality Among Women and Children: Evidence from Tajikistan

  • Original Article
  • Published:
The European Journal of Development Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Household-level agriculture-nutrition linkage (ANL) tends to be strong where food markets are imperfect. In such an environment, markets for cooking services may also be imperfect. Nutrition outcomes of household members, including intrahousehold inequality among women and children can depend on a household’s self-production of food and cooking services, provided both by household labors, particularly of women. Using the primary data in Tajikistan, we show that longer cooking-time by women in the household often strengthens household-level ANL and also reduces intrahousehold inequality in nutritional outcomes among women and children. These effects are stronger in areas with lower nighttime light intensity and for households with lower values of cooking assets. In a context where household-level ANL is strong, ANL may also depend on households’ self-production of complementary inputs, including cooking services. This dependence reveals both unique opportunities for and vulnerabilities of ANL for the rural poor.

Résumé

Les liens entre l’agriculture et la nutrition (en anglais : Agriculture-Nutrition Linkage, ANL) au niveau des foyers ont tendance à être forts là où les marchés sont imparfaits. Dans ces environnements, les marchés pour les services d’élaboration et de cuisson des repas peuvent aussi être imparfaits. La nutrition des membres d’un foyer, ainsi que l’inégalité nutritionnelle entre les femmes et les enfants du ménage, peuvent dépendre de la production d’aliments et des service de cuisson fournis au sein du foyer, souvent par le travail des femmes. Utilisant des données primaires au Tadjikistan, nous démontrons que des temps de cuisson plus longs par les femmes renforce l’ANL au niveau du foyer, et d’ailleurs réduit les inégalités nutritionnelles parmi les femmes et les enfants. Ces résultats sont plus marqués dans les régions ou il y a moins d’intensité lumineuse la nuit, et pour les foyers avec moins de ressources pour la cuisson. Dans les contextes ou l’ANL au niveau des foyers et élevée, l’ANL peut dépendre aussi d’autres contributions complémentaires, y inclus les services de cuisson. Cette dépendance révèle soit des opportunités uniques, soit des vulnérabilités ANL chez les pauvres rurales.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This paper uses several abbreviations for maintaining concision. Appendix A provides the list of these abbreviations.

  2. The paper does not directly provide evidence on intrahousehold inequality vis-à-vis men because of the lack of data on male nutritional outcomes. However, intrahousehold inequality among women (as evidenced in this paper), which is by itself important, also has a greater implication if inequality vis-à-vis men is greater. For example, if such gender inequality already exists, an additional inequality among women means some women members can be even more worse-off nutritionally, and a household can face a greater risk of double-burden of malnutrition within it (Global Nutrition Report 2020). Direct evidence of such inequality vis-à-vis men in nutritional outcomes has been emerging in Asia, including Bangladesh (D’Souza and Tandon 2019), India (Roy 2020) and Nepal (Harris-Fry et al. 2018). Similar (albeit less direct) evidence is also emerging in Tajikistan. For example, gender-differentiated roles in food acquisition and cooking, as well as beliefs and perceptions about nutritious food or taboos are widespread in Tajikistan (McNamara and Wood 2019; Wood et al. 2018), implying gender inequality in nutritional outcomes may be already fairly common in Tajikistan.

  3. Results are available from authors upon request.

  4. DEA is also suitable because it is particularly reliable in estimating efficiency where the markets for inputs and outputs are imperfect (Charnes et al. 1994), as is the case in rural areas in many developing countries.

  5. Controlling for the characteristics of respondents reporting time use is important not only because of self-selection. It is also because individual characteristics can be important determinants of time use; such determinants include marital status, whether having children or not, and the age/seniority of women (Zycherman 2013). The presence of other care-taking women in households can also allow particular women to devote more time to other activities like work or cooking (Zycherman 2013).

  6. Various studies suggest the variations on nutritional outcomes among women within the households depending on their demographic characteristics. For example, older women tend to be associated with greater weight and higher body mass index (BMI) (Hasan et al. 2017; Beal et al. 2018), but in other cases older women tend to suffer from more malnutrition (Oddo et al. 2012). These patterns also do not always hold everywhere. Older women are found to eat somewhat healthier in Viet Nam (Nguyen et al. 2018) and are more at risk of underweight in Bangladesh (Khanam et al. 2018).

  7. Detailed results for the remaining specifications are available from authors upon request.

  8. It is beyond the scope of this study to separate the effects of ANL and cooking-time into supply and demand for nutrition. We focus on equilibrium nutritional outcomes, and we interpret their improvements as positive, although strictly speaking, some of the seeming “improvement” may be due to the increased nutrition requirements as a result of greater engagements in agricultural production or cooking (for members who are reporting cooking-time). More precise interpretations must be addressed in future studies.

  9. Higher cooking technologies raise marginal returns to a unit of cooking-time. They may induce greater cooking-time if cooking is undertaken for commercial and income-earning purposes, because the demand curve is that of the market and is fairly flat. However, cooking for household members faces a declining demand curve, and thus higher cooking technologies become substitutes for cooking-time.

  10. An extreme example is as follows. If there is only one apple for two household members, the apple needs to be cut, incurring certain transaction costs. If there are two apples, each can simply be given to each person, without any transaction costs. If, however, there is additional apple (and thus a total of three apples), this additional apple is likely to have to be cut into half and shared by these two people, to equate their marginal utility. In this case, a greater quantity of food (apple) ends up increasing transactions costs for equating an individual’s marginal utility. If the transactions costs are too high and they give up sharing the third apple, two and one apples are consumed by each person, respectively, leading to inequality in consumption.

  11. The description in this section draws largely on Takeshima et al. (2017).

References

  • Allen L & S Gillespie. 2001. What Works? A Review of the Efficacy and Effectiveness of Nutrition Interventions. Geneva: United Nations Administrative Committee on Coordination Sub-Committee on Nutrition; Asian Development Bank.

  • Amare, M., C. Arndt, K. Abay, and T. Benson. 2020. Urbanization and Child Nutritional Outcomes. World Bank Economic Review 34 (1): 63–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beal, T., et al. 2018. A Review of Child Stunting Determinants in Indonesia. Maternal & Child Nutrition 14 (4): e12617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhandari, S., et al. 2016. Dietary Intake Patterns and Nutritional Status of Women of Reproductive Age in Nepal: Findings from a Health Survey. Archives of Public Health 74 (2): 1–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bia, M., and A. Mattei. 2008. A Stata Package for the Estimation of the Dose-Response Function through Adjustment for the Generalized Propensity Score. Stata Journal 8 (3): 354–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bodnar, L.M., M. Davidian, A.M. Siega-Riz, and A.A. Tsiatis. 2004. Marginal Structural Models for Analyzing Causal Effects of Time-Dependent Treatments: An Application in Perinatal Epidemiology. American Journal of Epidemiology 159 (10): 926–934.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charnes, A., W. Cooper, A. Lewin, and L. Seiford. 1994. Data Envelopment Analysis: Theory, Methodology, and Applications. New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • D’Souza, A., and S. Tandon. 2019. Intrahousehold Nutritional Inequities in Rural Bangladesh. Economic Development and Cultural Change 67 (3): 625–657.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Efron, B. 1979. Bootstrap Methods: Another Look at the Jackknife. Annals of Statistics 7: 101–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esquivel, V., D. Budlender, N. Folbre, and I. Hirway. 2008. Explorations: Time-Use Surveys in the South. Feminist Economics 14 (3): 107–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fan, S., S. Yosef, and R. Pandya-Lorch. 2019. Agriculture for Improved Nutrition: Seizing the Momentum. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • FAO (Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations) and FHI 360. 2016. Minimum Dietary Diversity for Women: A Guide for Measurement. Rome: FAO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Finaret, A.B., et al. 2018. Longitudinal Analysis of the Intrahousehold Distribution of Foods in Rural Nepal: Relative Variability of Child Dietary Quality across Age and Sex Cohorts. Food Policy 79: 101–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flores, C.A., and O.A. Mitnik. 2013. Comparing Treatments across Labor Markets: An Assessment of Nonexperimental Multiple-Treatment Strategies. Review of Economics and Statistics 95 (5): 1691–1707.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haddad, L., J. Hoddinott, and H. Alderman. 1997. Intrahousehold Resource Allocation in Developing Countries. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris-Fry, H.A., N. Shrestha, A. Costello, and N.M. Saville. 2017. Determinants of Intra-household Food Allocation Between Adults in South Asia—A Systematic Review. International Journal for Equity in Health 16 (107): 1–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris-Fry, H.A., et al. 2018. Status and Determinants of Intra-household Food Allocation in Rural Nepal. European Journal of Clinical Nutrition 72: 1524–1536.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hasan, M., I. Sutradhar, A.S.M. Shahabuddin, and M. Sarker. 2017. Double Burden of Malnutrition among Bangladeshi Women: A Literature Review. Cureus 9 (12): 1–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, V.J., A. Storeygard, and D.N. Weil. 2012. Measuring Economic Growth from Outer Space. American Economic Review 102: 994–1028.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirano, K., and G. Imbens. 2004. The Propensity Score with Continuous Treatments. In Applied Bayesian Modeling and Causal Inference from Incomplete-Data Perspectives, ed. A. Gelman and X.L. Meng, 73–84. Chichester: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirvonen, K., and J. Hoddinott. 2017. Agricultural Production and Children’s Diets: Evidence from Rural Ethiopia. Agricultural Economics 48 (4): 469–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huber, M. 2014. Identifying Causal Mechanisms (Primarily) Based on Inverse Probability Weighting. Journal of Applied Econometrics 29 (6): 920–943.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IFPRI (International Food Policy Research Institute). 2016. Feed the Future Tajikistan 2015: Zone of Influence Interim Assessment Report. Washington, DC.

  • IFPRI (International Food Policy Research Institute). 2019. Feed the Future Tajikistan 2018: Zone of Influence Interim Assessment Report. Washington, DC.

  • Imbens, G.W. 2000. The Role of the Propensity Score in Estimating Dose-Response Functions. Biometrika 87 (3): 706–710.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jayachandran, S., and R. Pande. 2017. Why Are Indian Children So Short? The Role of Birth Order and Son Preference. American Economic Review 107 (9): 2600–2629.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnston, D., S. Stevano, H.J. Malapit, E. Hull, and S. Kadiyala. 2018. Time Use as an Explanation for the Agri-nutrition Disconnect? Evidence from Rural Areas in Low and Middle-Income Countries. Food Policy 76: 8–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kadiyala, S., J. Harris, D. Headey, S. Yosef, and S. Gillespie. 2014. Agriculture and nutrition in India: mapping evidence to pathways. Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences 1331 (1): 43–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khanam, R., et al. 2018. Levels and Correlates of Nutritional Status of Women of Childbearing Age in Rural Bangladesh. Public Health Nutrition 21 (16): 3037–3047.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kluve J., H. Schneider, A. Uhlendorff, and Z. Zhao. 2007. Evaluating Continuous Training Programs Using the Generalized Propensity Score. IZA Discussion Paper 3255. Bonn, Germany: Institute for the Study of Labor.

  • Komatsu, H., H.J.L. Malapit, and S. Theis. 2018. Does Women’s Time in Domestic Work and Agriculture Affect Women’s and Children’s Dietary Diversity? Evidence from Bangladesh, Nepal, Cambodia, Ghana, and Mozambique. Food Policy 79: 256–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar, N., J. Harris, and R. Rawat. 2015. If They Grow It, Will They Eat and Grow? Evidence from Zambia on Agricultural Diversity and Child Undernutrition. Journal of Development Studies 51 (8): 1060–1077.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leslie, J. 1988. Women’s Work and Child Nutrition in the Third World. World Development 16 (11): 1341–1362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malapit, H. 2019. Women in Agriculture and the Implications for Nutrition. In Agriculture for Improved Nutrition: Seizing the Momentum, ed. S. Fan, S. Yosef, and R. Pandya-Lorch. Washington, DC: IFPRI.

    Google Scholar 

  • McNamara, K., and E. Wood. 2019. Food Taboos, Health Beliefs, and Gender: Understanding Household Food Choice and Nutrition in Rural Tajikistan. Journal of Health, Population and Nutrition 38 (1): 17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nguyen, C., et al. 2018. Low Dietary Intakes of Essential Nutrients during Pregnancy in Vietnam. Nutrients 10 (8): 1025.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oddo, V.M., et al. 2012. Predictors of Maternal and Child Double Burden of Malnutrition in Rural Indonesia and Bangladesh. American Journal of Clinical Nutrition 95 (4): 951–958.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paolisso, M.J., K. Hallman, L. Haddad, and S. Regmi. 2002. Does Cash Crop Adoption Detract from Child Care Provision? Evidence from Rural Nepal. Economic Development and Cultural Change 50 (2): 313–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pitt, M.M., M.R. Rosenzweig, and M.N. Hassan. 1990. Productivity, Health, and Inequality in the Intrahousehold Distribution of Food in Low-Income Countries. American Economic Review 80 (5): 1139–1156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rao, N., and S. Raju. 2020. Gendered Time, Seasonality, and Nutrition: Insights from Two Indian Districts. Feminist Economics 26 (2): 95–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ricci, J.A., et al. 1996. The Significance of Children’s Age in Estimating the Effect of Maternal Time Use on Children’s Well-Being. Social Science and Medicine 42 (5): 651–659.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roy, P. 2020. Gender, Time Use, and Food Consumption in India. Gender, Technology and Development 24 (3): 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruel, M.T., A.R. Quisumbing, and M. Balagamwala. 2018. Nutrition-Sensitive Agriculture: What Have We Learned So Far? Global Food Security 17: 128–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shively, G., C. Sununtnasuk, and M. Brown. 2015. Agricultural Diversity and Child Stunting in Nepal. Health Place 35: 37–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, L.C., U. Ramakrishnan, A. Ndiaye, L. Haddad, and R. Martorell. 2003. The Importance of Women’s Status for Child Nutrition in Developing Countries. Research Report 131. International food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI), Washington, DC.

  • Takeshima, H., R. Adhikari, S. Shivakoti, B.D. Kaphle, and A. Kumar. 2017. Heterogeneous Returns to Chemical Fertilizer at the Intensive Margins: Insights from Nepal. Food Policy 69: 97–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Takeshima, H., et al. 2018. Agriculture–Nutrition Linkages in Tajikistan: Evidence from Household Survey Data. IFPRI Discussion Paper 01770.

  • Takeshima, H., K. Akramov, A. Park, J. Ilyasov, and T. Ergasheva. 2019. Agriculture-Nutrition Linkages, Cooking-Time, Intra-household Equality Among Women and Children: Evidence from Tajikistan. IFPRI Discussion Paper 01882.

  • Weinberger, K., and I. Swai. 2006. Consumption of Traditional Vegetables in Central and Northeastern Tanzania. Ecology of Food and Nutrition 45 (2): 87–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood, E., K. McNamara, A. Kowalewska, and N. Ludgate. 2018. Household Decision-Making Around Food in Rural Tajikistan: A Cross-Sectional Study to Help Extension Workers in the Field. Food & Nutrition Research 62: 1–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • WHO (World Health Organization). 2010. Indicators for Assessing Infant and Young Child Feeding Practices. Part 2: Measurement. Geneva: WHO. https://www.who.int/nutrition/publications/infantfeeding/9789241599290/en/.

  • World Bank. 2019. World Development Indicators. Washington DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zycherman, A. 2013. The Changing Value of Food: Localizing Modernity among the Tsimane Indians of Lowland Bolivia. PhD dissertation, Columbia University, New York.

Download references

Acknowledgements

We appreciate the anonymous reviewers and Journal editor for providing constructive comments and suggestions. We thank the participants of the Annual Eurasian Food Security Conference in Dushanbe, 2017, the Third and the Fourth Annual International Conference on Agriculture, Food Security, and Nutrition in Eurasia in Moscow, 2018 and 2019, and the seminar participants at the Tajik Academy of Agricultural Sciences (TAAS) in September 2018 for providing useful feedbacks for the earlier version of the paper, and we thank the field staff from Zerkalo for the 2015 and 2018 data collection. We also thank the United States Agency for International Development (USAID), the CGIAR Research Program on Policies, Institutions, and Markets (PIM), and the CGIAR Research Program on Agriculture for Nutrition and Health (A4NH), which are led by the International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI), as well as the government of Japan through its support to IFPRI, for providing financial support to conduct this study. Any opinions expressed here belong to the authors and do not reflect those of its collaborators. The authors are responsible for all remaining errors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hiroyuki Takeshima.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

Authors have no conflict of interests to declare regarding this manuscript.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A: List of Abbreviations

ADS: Agricultural diversity score

ANL: Agriculture-nutrition linkage

APP: Agricultural production practices

APV: Agricultural production values

BMI: Body mass index

CMAD: Children’s minimum acceptable diet

CMDD: Children’s minimum acceptable dietary diversity

DEA: Data envelopment analyses

GDP: Gross domestic product

GPS: Generalized propensity score

GPS-IPW: Generalized-propensity-score-based inverse probability weighting method

IFPRI: International Food Policy Research Institute

IPW: Inverse probability weighted

IV: Instrumental variables

IVGMM: Instrumental-variable generalized method of moments

NGPS-IPW: Nested GPS-IPW

PR: Primary respondent

SD: Standard deviation

TAWA: Tajikistan Agriculture and Water Activity

USAID: United States Agency for International Development

VCE: Value of cooking equipment

WAZ: Children’s weight-for-age Z-score

WDS: Women’s dietary diversity score

WDSM: Women’s minimum acceptable dietary diversity score

WHZ: Children’s weight-for-height Z-score

WLS: Weighted least square

WRA: Women of reproductive age

ZOI: Zone of influence

Appendix B: Theoretical Framework

Role of Household Cooking-Time on ANL

The demand for nutritional outcomes of individual \( i \) (\( N_{i} \)) in household \( h \) is selected by maximizing utility,

$$ U = U\left( {N_{i} ;Z_{h,i} } \right) $$
(6)

which depends on the inherent preference that depends on individual and household characteristics \( Z_{h,i} \). Here, for simplicity, we drop the subscript \( h \) and \( i \) (we will reinstate them later when discussing intrahousehold equality).

\( N \) is supplied by available food F (either home produced \( A \) or purchased \( F_{P} \)), household members’ cooking-time \( T \), and functions of cooking technologies C, level of food-market access \( M \), and again Z (which can affect non-food sources of nutrition).

$$ N = f\left( {F, T;C,M, Z} \right). $$
(7)

Note \( T \) does not include cooking provided by non-household members, such as purchased cooking services. The equilibrium nutritional outcome \( N^{*} \) is jointly determined by these demand and supply factors.Footnote 8

In low-income countries with food poverty (so that nutrition is still constrained by food availability F), we are likely to have

$$ \frac{{\partial N^{*} }}{\partial F} > 0. $$
(8)

The ANL literature generally suggests that, in rural areas with low \( M \), we tend to have

$$ \frac{\partial F}{\partial A} > 0 $$
(9)

because of relatively higher costs for acquiring \( F_{P} \) given \( Z \).

Because low M would indicate relative scarcity of pre-cooked food, or most food items must be cooked before becoming digestible, or retaining bioavailability of nutrients in food items may require more careful cooking, \( \frac{{\partial N^{*} }}{\partial F} \) responds more positively to cooking inputs. Furthermore, because low M is also associated with high cooking-service costs, cooking inputs are supplied mostly by households’ own cooking inputs, \( T \). Thus,

$$ \frac{{\partial^{2} N^{*} }}{\partial F\partial T} > 0. $$
(10)

It is also likely that cooking-time T and cooking technologies are substitutes, so that \( \frac{{\partial^{2} N^{*} }}{\partial T\partial C} < 0 \).Footnote 9 Therefore, combined with (10), we are likely to have

$$ \frac{{\partial \left( {\frac{{\partial^{2} N^{*} }}{\partial F\partial T}} \right)}}{\partial C} < 0. $$
(11)

Because we have \( \frac{\partial F}{\partial A} > 0 \), condition (11) suggests

$$ \frac{{\partial \left( {\frac{{\partial^{2} N^{*} }}{\partial A\partial T}} \right)}}{\partial C} < 0. $$
(12)

Household cooking-time \( T \) may also be substituted with \( M \), because as \( M \) rises, the access to either pre-cooked food or affordable cooking services may improve. Similarly, higher M may be associated with more urban income-earning opportunities which can provide alternative means to improve nutrition, and thus higher M raises the opportunity cost of T for most individuals. Therefore, \( \frac{{\partial^{2} N^{*} }}{\partial T\partial M} < 0 \). Using the same argument as cooking technologies, we then have

$$ \frac{{\partial \left( {\frac{{\partial^{2} N^{*} }}{\partial A\partial T}} \right)}}{\partial M} < 0. $$
(13)

Conditions (12) and (13) lead to hypothesis 1:

Hypothesis 1

Conditional on household characteristics Z, household agricultural production (greater diversity or production scale) and cooking-time is generally complementary in improving equilibrium nutritional outcomes of women and children, and this effect is stronger for households with lower cooking technologies or in rural areas.

The hypothesis 1 may not hold if some of the aforementioned conditions fail. Therefore, whether hypothesis 1 holds or not is an important empirical question.

Intrahousehold Inequality Among Women and Children

Equilibrium nutritional outcomes of each household member maximize a certain utility function. Based on the realization of \( N_{i}^{*} \), some indicators of intrahousehold equality \( \sigma^{*} \) are obtained:

$$ N_{i}^{*} = \arg { \hbox{max} }_{{N_{i} }} U\left( {N_{i} ;Z_{h,i} } \right) \sigma_{h}^{*} = \sigma \left( {N_{i}^{*} ;Z_{h,i} } \right).$$
(14)

Note \( \sigma_{h}^{*} \) is conditional on Z (and its intrahousehold variation) because observable Z is assumed to explain most of the variations in intrahousehold allocations (including activity-level, pregnancy status, etc.).

It is beyond the scope of this study to assess how the utility function is maximized. For the sake of presenting a theoretical framework, we consider the case in which allocation is made by a decision-maker in the household, with the goal of maximizing the aggregate consumer surplus (or utility) of all members while meeting the resource constraint. In this particular case, \( N_{i}^{*} \) is determined such that

$$ \left. {\frac{{\partial U\left( {N_{i} ;Z} \right)}}{{\partial N_{i} }}} \right|_{{N_{i} = \hat{N}_{i} }} = \left. {\frac{{\partial U\left( {N_{j} ;Z} \right)}}{{\partial N_{j} }}} \right|_{{N_{j} = \hat{N}_{j} }} \forall j \ne i $$
(15)

so that every member’s marginal utility from an additional unit of nutrition is equated. When this holds, and if the utility function is the same across members conditional on \( Z \) (so that all variations in inherent preference are solely explained by observable characteristics), we should have \( \sigma_{h}^{*} = \sigma \left( {N_{i}^{*} ;Z} \right) = 0 \), meaning perfect intrahousehold equality.

Even in such a case, \( N_{i}^{*} \) may deviate from \( \hat{N}_{i} \) if transaction costs in achieving the aforementioned allocations are greater than the returns from reallocations. These transaction costs will thus affect \( \sigma_{h}^{*} \), conditional on \( Z \).

\( A \) and \( T \) may jointly reduce \( \sigma_{h}^{*} \) if they affect such transactions costs in such ways. For example, the greater overall availability of food and longer cooking-time may reduce such transactions costs. However, they can also operate in opposite ways.Footnote 10 The discussion here is made for illustrative purposes, and how \( A \) and \( T \) affect \( \sigma_{h}^{*} \) conditional on \( Z \) is therefore an empirical question which we aim to investigate.

Hypothesis 2

Household agricultural production (greater diversity or production scale) and cooking-time are generally complementary in reducing intrahousehold nutritional inequality among women and children, and this effect is stronger for households with lower cooking technologies or in rural areas.

Technical Efficiency

The theoretical framework on the effects of technical efficiency in agriculture is similar to hypothesis 1. With higher efficiency, either greater \( A \) or greater resources allocated for other purposes can improve nutritional outcomes. On the one hand, if greater \( A \) is achieved, and if cooking-time \( T \) is complementary, then higher technical efficiency and \( T \) can be complementary to improving nutrition. On the other hand, the opportunity costs of resources used to raise technical efficiency in the area may be high (for example, they can be used for other means to more directly raise nutrition) to produce the same amount of food, or higher technical efficiency may not lead to sufficient food availability if households simply reduce inputs use. In such a case, raising technical efficiency may not improve nutritional outcomes.

Hypothesis 3

Higher technical efficiency in agriculture and cooking-time are complementary to each other in improving nutritional outcomes, and this effect is stronger for households with lower cooking technologies or in rural areas; these conditions may largely hold in the current setting of the studied area in Tajikistan.

Appendix C: Generalized-Propensity-Score-Based Inverse Probability Weighting Method

GPS is estimated in the following way (Hirano and Imbens 2004; Bia and Mattei 2008).Footnote 11 Each household \( h = 1, \ldots , H \) is associated with a set of potential outcomes \( \varpi_{h} \left( {T_{h} } \right) \), which is conditional on treatment \( T_{h} \) (cooking-time in our case). Each \( h \) is associated with observed covariates \( Z_{h,i} \), cooking-time \( T_{h} \in \left[ {t_{0} ,t_{1} } \right] \) where \( t_{0} \) and \( t_{1} \) are the lower and upper bounds of treatment level.

The conditional density of \( T \) given the covariates \( Z \) can be denoted as \( r\left( {T,Z} \right) = f_{T|Z} (T|Z) \). Specific GPS, based on the observed \( T_{h} ,Z_{h}, \) can be denoted as \( R_{h} = r\left( {T_{h} ,Z_{h} } \right) \). It is assumed that, within strata with the same \( r\left( {T,Z} \right) \), the probability that \( T = T_{h} \) is independent of \( Z \), which is another way of saying that \( T_{h} \) is independent of \( Z_{h} \) once conditional on \( R_{h} \), so that the changes in outcomes can be attributed solely to \( T_{h} \) once conditional on \( R_{h} \).

GPS is estimated in the following way. First, \( T_{h} \) or its particular transformation (such as Diewert transformation) \( g\left( {T_{h} } \right) \) are regressed on \( X_{h} \), through the maximum likelihood method with normally distributed disturbance term. This regression estimates \( r\left( {T,Z} \right) = \frac{1}{{\sqrt {2\pi \hat{\sigma }^{2} } }}\exp \left[ { - \frac{1}{{2\hat{\sigma }^{2} }}\left\{ {g\left( T \right) - \zeta \left( {\hat{\gamma },Z} \right)} \right\}} \right] \) in which \( \zeta \left( {\hat{\gamma },Z} \right) \) is a function of \( Z \) and parameters \( \hat{\gamma } \). Given \( r\left( {T,Z} \right) \), we compute \( R_{h} = r\left( {T_{h} ,X_{h} } \right) \) for each observation \( h \).

Balancing-Tests

Balancing tests for GPS methods are typically conducted by comparing GPS-adjusted means of \( Z_{h} \) across subgroups that are defined based on the range of \( T_{h} \). A standard approach (Hirano and Imbens 2004; Kluve et al. 2007) is to split the sample into three subsamples \( G_{j} \left( {j = 1, 2, 3} \right) \) based on the terciles of \( T_{h} \), divide each subsample into five blocks \( G_{jk} \left( {k = 1, 2, 3, 4, 5} \right) \) based on the quintiles of the \( R\left( {T_{h,j}^{m} ,Z_{h} } \right) \) evaluated at the median of \( T_{h} \) within the tercile \( j \), and then calculate the t-statistics for the equality of means of \( Z_{h} \)’s between blocks \( G_{jk} \) and \( G_{\xi k} \left( {\xi \ne j} \right) \).

Appendix D: More Results

See Tables 14, 15, and 16.

Table 14 Factors associated with APP (probit).
Table 15 Generalized-propensity-score estimation of cooking-time.
Table 16 Full results for some of the main equations on the effects of crop diversification score on various nutritional outcomes estimated from IPW (statistically significant signs)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Takeshima, H., Akramov, K., Park, A. et al. Agriculture-Nutrition Linkages, Cooking-Time, Intrahousehold Equality Among Women and Children: Evidence from Tajikistan. Eur J Dev Res 34, 940–977 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41287-021-00379-z

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41287-021-00379-z

Keywords

Navigation