Skip to main content
Log in

The impact of economic and political factors on popularity in France (1981–2017)

  • Original Article
  • Published:
French Politics Aims and scope

Abstract

In this article, we study a popularity function for the popularity of the French political parties (1981Q2–2017Q1). At first, we suppose that voters have a retrospective behaviour according to the reward-punishment model in a closed economy. We show that the unemployment rate has a significant influence on the popularity of the French political parties and find unfavourable results for the partisan hypothesis. The analysis also indicates that economic openness has an influence on popularity, thus a partly expected result for the asymmetry hypothesis: punishment without any reward. For the political variables, significant influence of the honeymoon effect, the second-order elections (regional or European) and the congresses of the Socialist party are also found to be significant.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In the model of Hibbs (1981), voters judge economic performance of the government in a relative way by comparing it with the previous party and government and voters are not very myopic and take into account economic performance over the last 4 years.

  2. Since the 2007 French presidential election, the popularity of the Left (approximated by the popularity of the Socialist party) is not a good predictor of the vote for the Left at the second round of the French presidential election.

  3. As the popularity variable is not simply a political variable but has an economic part, we shall mention it explicitly when it is used.

  4. According to Lewis-Beck and Paldam (2000), voters have more retrospective behaviour than forward-looking behaviour, but the difference between these two models is weak.

  5. In the partisan political cycles originally developed for the USA, the left-wing party (democratic) attaches more importance to the fight against unemployment and the right-wing party (republican) attaches more importance to the fight against inflation.

  6. Kayser and Grafstrom (2019) distinguish four voting models: the unemployment competence (direct interests), the growth competence, the class interests of Peltzman (1992) and the material issues models.

  7. Kayser and Grafstrom (2019) write that a variant of this argument is to suppose that left-wing parties hold a reputation for competence in the fight against unemployment and right-wing parties in the fight against inflation.

  8. Letterie and Swank (1997), and Swank (1998) construct a complete model with partisan and competence (reward-punishment) variables.

  9. The results of Hellwig and Samuels (2007) seem favourable for ‘the government constraint hypothesis’, but it would be necessary to compare these results with those obtained with an estimation with economic variables without the interaction of the economy with openness.

  10. Nannestad and Paldam (1997) and Enkelmann (2014) write that from a rational choice perspective, the (grievance) asymmetry simply reflects the fact that people are risk-averse.

  11. Fair (1978) uses as the dependent variable the vote for the democratic candidate at the American presidential elections and details a theoretical model of electoral choice.

  12. The most used dependent variable is the popularity of the President or of the Prime Minister (this is closely links to the vote for the outgoing presidential or parliamentary majority). Pissarides (1980), Borooah and van der Ploeg (1982) and Borooah and Boroaah (1990) use as the dependent variable the difference between the popularity of the government and the popularity of the opposition. Borooah and van der Ploeg (1982), and Borooah and Boroaah (1990) explain the choice of the dependent variable with a theoretical model (a logit model).

  13. We retain the data of the third month of every quarter when the data were monthly.

  14. Unit root tests for the popularity-dependent variable POPLR have given the following results: with the ADF (augmented Dickey-Fuller) and the SIC or modified SIC criterion, the Phillips-Perron, the KPSS tests, the POPLR series has not a unit root at 5 per cent level; the Perron test with an endogenous break point at 1996Q4 (with a break in the level or in the slope). The different unit root tests show that the ΔPOPLR series is stationary at 5 per cent level. Unit root tests for the UNEMN, GGDPN and INFLN economic independent variables have given the following results: with the ADF (augmented Dickey-Fuller) and the SIC or modified SIC criterion, the Phillips-Perron tests, the results are ambiguous for the UNEMN, GGDPN series, and the INFLN series is stationary at 5 per cent level; the different unit root tests show that the ΔUNEMN and ΔGGDPN series are stationary at 5 per cent level.

  15. We use this popularity index for the French presidential elections (1981–2012) and a quite similar popularity index: (POPL + POPLR)/2 for the French legislative elections (1986–2012 and 1986–2017); see Auberger (2018).

  16. We use OCDE data for the unemployment rate because, with INSEE data, the unemployment rate may not be known until 2 months after the end of a quarter.

  17. When we suppose that voters are sophisticated, we study the effect of the difference between the national economic situation and the global economic situation on popularity. With this hypothesis, the government has the capacity to influence a globalized economy and must have better economic performances than the global economy. The results obtained (statistical indicators) are not clearly different (more satisfactory) than with only the national economic situation; see Auberger (2016); then it is not necessary to suppose that voters are sophisticated. We also note that the estimated coefficient of the unemployment variable in a globalized economy is very slightly lower in absolute value than in a closed economy (1981Q2-2014Q4).

  18. The clarity of responsibility variables are not significant at 10 per cent level (ENEP × I and NPG × I) where the ENEP variable is the effective number of parties in parliament and the NPG variable is the number of parties in government. Dassonneville et Lewis-Beck (2014) do not multiply the ENEP and NPG variables by I (equals to 1 or to − 1) while they study the vote for the Left and we can question this. However, these variables seem questionable when we do not multiply them by an economic variable to study their influence but then there may be a multicollinearity problem.

  19. For the honeymoon variable, different variables have been tested with similar results.

  20. The estimated coefficients of the ΔGDPL, ΔGDPLOE, ΔINFLNL and ΔINFLNLOE variables are not significant at 10 per cent level.

References

  • Alesina, Alberto. 1987. Macroeconomic Policy in a Two-Party System as a Repeated Game. Quaterly Journal of Economics 102: 651–678.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, Alberto, and Howard Rosenthal. 1995. Partisan Politics. Divided Government and the Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, Alberto, Nouriel Roubini, and Gerald Cohen. 1997. Political Cycles and the Macroeconomy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, Christopher J. 2000. Economic Voting and Political Context: A Comparative Perspective. Electoral Studies 19: 151–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auberger, Antoine. 2001. Popularité. Cycles et politique économique. University of Paris 2: Thèse de doctorat en sciences économiques.

  • Auberger, Antoine. 2011. The Popularity Functions. A Survey of the Literature. University of Paris 2 (and University of Paris 1): Working Paper.

  • Auberger, Antoine. 2016. The Impact of Economic and Political Factors on Popularity for France (19812014). University of Paris 2: Working Paper.

  • Auberger, Antoine. 2018. Vote, Popularity, Unemployment and French legislative Elections. University of Paris 2: Working Paper.

  • Arel-Bundock, Vincent, André Blais, and Ruth Dassonneville. 2019. Do Voters Benchmark Economic Performance? British Journal of Political Science. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123418000236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aytaç, Selim Erdem. 2018. Relative Economic Performance and the Incumbent Vote: A Reference Point Theory. The Journal of Politics 80: 16–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, Howard S., and Douglas H. Price. 1975. Voter Response to Short-Run Economic Conditions: The Asymmetric Effect of Prosperity and Recession. American Political Science Review 69: 1240–1254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borooah, Vani K., and Vidya Boroaah. 1990. Economic Performance and Political Popularity in the Republic of Ireland. Public Choice 67: 65–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borooah, Vani K., and Frederick Van der Ploeg. 1982. British Government Popularity and Economic Performance: A Comment. The Economic Journal 92: 405–410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boukari, Mamadou, and Etienne Farvaque. 2019. Who Profits from Legislative Activism? An Analysis of the President and Prime Minister Popularity. French Politics 17: 64–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlsen, Fredrik. 2000. Unemployment, Inflation and Government Popularity—Are There Partisan Effects? Electoral Studies 19: 141–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cho, Sungdai, and Garry Young. 2002. The Asymmetric Impact of Inflation on Presidential Approval. Politics & Policy 30: 401–430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Courbis, Raymond. 1995. La conjoncture économique. la popularité politique et les perspectives électorales dans la France d’aujourd’hui. Journal de la société de statistique de Paris 136: 47–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dassonneville, Ruth, and Michael S. Lewis-Beck. 2013. Economic Policy Voting and Incumbency: Unemployment in Western Europe. Political Science Research and Methods 1: 53–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dassonneville, Ruth, and Michael S. Lewis-Beck. 2014. Macroeconomics. Economic Crisis and Electoral Outcomes: A National European Pool. Acta Politica 49: 372–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and Brothers Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duch, Raymond M., and Randy Stevenson. 2008. Voting in Context: How Political and Economic Institutions Condition Election Results. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Duch, Raymond M., and Randy Stevenson. 2010. The Global Economy, Competency, and the Economic Vote. The Journal of Politics 72: 105–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Enkelmann, Sören. 2014. Government Popularity and the Economy: First Evidence from German Microdata. Empirical Economics 46: 999–1017.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fair Ray, C. 1978. The Effect of Economic Events on Votes for President. The Review of Economics and Statistics 60: 159–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerstlé, Jacques, and Abel François. 2011. Médiatisation de l’économie et fabrication de la popularité du président français (2007–2010). Revue française de science politique 61: 249–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodhart, Charles A.E., and Raj J. Bhansali. 1970. Political Economy. Political Studies 18: 43–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Headrick, Barbara, and David J. Lanoue. 1991. Attention, Asymmetry, and Government Popularity in Britain. Western Political Quaterly 44: 67–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hellwig, Timothy T. 2001. Interdependence, Government Constraints, and Economic Voting. The Journal of Politics 63: 1141–1162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hellwig, Timothy. 2007. Economic Openness, Policy Uncertainty, and the Dynamics of Government Support. Electoral Studies 26: 772–786.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hellwig, Timothy, and David Samuels. 2007. Voting in Open Economies. The Electoral Consequences of Globalization. Comparative Political Studies 40: 283–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs Jr., Douglas A. 1977. Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policies and Outcomes in the United States. American Political Science Review 71: 1467–1487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, Douglas A. Jr. 1981. Economics and Politics in France: Economic Performance and Mass Political Support for Presidents Pompidou and Giscard d’Estaing. European Journal of Political Research 9: 133–145, published in French. 1983. Performance économique et fonction de popularité des présidents Pompidou et Giscard d’Estaing. Revue d’économie politique 1: 44-61.

  • Hobolt, Sara, James Tilley, and Susan Banducci. 2013. Clarity of Responsibility: How Government Cohesion Conditions Performance Voting. European Journal of Political Research 52: 164–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kappe, Roland. 2018. Asymmetric Evaluations: Government Popularity and Economic Performance in the United Kingdom. Electoral Studies 53: 133–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kayser, Mark A., and Cassandra Grafström. 2019. The Material Issues Vote: Asymmetry Partisan Accountability for the Economy. Hertie School Berlin: Working Paper.

  • Key Jr., Vladimir O. 1966. The Responsible Electorate. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kiewiet, Roderick D. 1981. Policy-Oriented Voting in Response to Economic Issues. The American Political Science Review 75: 448–459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirchgässner, Gebhard. 1985. Rationality, Causality and the Relation Between Economic Conditions and the Popularity of Parties. An Empirical Investigation for the Federal Republic of Germany 1971–1982. European Economic Review 28: 243–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirchgässner, Gebhard. 1991. Economic Conditions and the Popularity of West German Parties: Before and After the 1982 Government Change. In Economics and Politics—The Calculus of Support, ed. Helmut Norpoth, Michael S. Lewis-Beck, and Jean-Dominique Lafay, 103–122. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirchgässner, Gebhard. 2019. Voting and popularity. In The Oxford Handbook of Public Choice., eds. Congleton, Roger D., Bernard Grofman, and Stefan Voigt, vol. 2, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

  • Kramer, Gerald H. 1971. Short-Term Fluctuations in U.S. Voting Behavior, 1896–1964. The American Political Science, Review 65: 131–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lafay, Jean-Dominique. 1981. Situation économétrique et comportements politiques: bilan des études empiriques et analyse du cas français. Actes du colloque de l’association française de sciences économiques.

  • Lafay, Jean-Dominique, and Marie Servais. 2000. The impact of political scandals on popularity and votes. in How France Votes. Michael S. Lewis-Beck, ed. 189–205, New York: Chatham House, reprinted. 2002. Homo Oeconomicus XIX: 153–170.

  • Letterie, Wilko, and Otto H. Swank. 1997. Electoral and Partisan Cycles Between US Economic Performance and Presidential Popularity: A Comment on Stephen E. Haynes. Applied Economics 29: 1585–1592.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis-Beck, Michael S. 1980. Economic Conditions and Executive Popularity: the French Experience. American Journal of Political Science 24: 306–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis-Beck, Michael S. 1985. Une modèle de prévision des élections législatives françaises (avec une application pour 1986). Revue française de science politique 35: 1080–1091.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis-Beck, Michael S., Eric Bélanger, and Christine Fauvelle-Aymar. 2008. Forecasting the 2007 French Presidential Election: Ségolène Royal and the Iowa Model. French Politics 6: 106–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis-Beck, Michael S., and Martin Paldam. 2000. Economic Voting: An Introduction. Electoral Studies 19: 113–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis-Beck, Michael S., and Mary Stegmaier. 2013. The VP-Function Revisited: A Survey of the Literature on Vote and Popularity Functions After Over 40 Years. Public Choice 157: 367–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maloney, John, and Andrew Pickering. 2015. Voting and the Economic Cycle. Public Choice 162: 119–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, John E. 1970. Presidential Popularity from Truman to Johnson. American Political Science Review 64: 18–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, Dennis C. 2003. Public Choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nadeau, Richard, Michael S. Lewis-Beck, and Eric Bélanger. 2010. Electoral Forecasting in France: A Multi-equation Solution. International Journal of Forecasting 26: 11–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nannestad, Peter, and Martin Paldam. 1994. The VP-Function: A Survey of the Literature on Vote and Popularity Functions After 25 Years. Public Choice 79: 213–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nannestad, Peter, and Martin Paldam. 1997. The Grievance Asymmetry Revisited: A Micro Study of Economic Voting in Denmark, 1986–92. European Journal of Political Economy 13: 81–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neck, Reinhard, and Sohbet Karbuz. 1997. Econometric Estimations of Popularity Functions: A Case Study for Austria. Public Choice 91: 57–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paldam, Martin. 1981. A Preliminary Survey of the Theories and Findings on Vote and Popularity Functions. European Journal of Political Research 9: 181–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, Sam. 1992. Voters as Fiscal Conservatives. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 107: 327–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pissarides, Christopher A. 1980. British Government Popularity and Economic Performance. The Economic Journal 90: 569–581.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosa, Jean-Jacques, and Daniel Amson. 1976. Conditions économiques et élections: une analyse politico-économétrique (1920–1973). Revue française de science politique 26: 1101–1124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanders, David. 2005. The Political Economy of UK Party Support, 1997–2004: Forecasts for the 2005 General Election. Journal of Elections, Public Opinion and Parties 15: 47–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, George J. 1973. Short-Term Fluctuations in U.S. Voting Behavior, 1896–1964. American Economic Review 63: 131–143.

    Google Scholar 

  • Swank, Otto H. 1993. Popularity Functions Based on the Partisan Theory. Public Choice 75: 339–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swank, Otto H. 1995. Rational Voters in a Partisanship Model. Social Choice and Welfare 12: 13–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swank, Otto H. 1998. Partisan Policies, Macroeconomic Performance and Political Support. Journal of Macroeconomics 30: 367–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veiga, Francisco J., and Linda G. Veiga. 2004. Popularity Functions, Partisan Effects, and Support in Parliament. Economics and Politics 16: 101–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Many thanks to Robert Elgie for his interest and support as well as to Amy Mazur and the reviewer. John Wisdom’s was a great help on the English fluency of this piece.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Antoine Auberger.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

See Table 5.

Table 5 Descriptive statistics of variables (1981Q2–2017Q1)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Auberger, A. The impact of economic and political factors on popularity in France (1981–2017). Fr Polit 17, 451–467 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41253-019-00103-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41253-019-00103-8

Keywords

Navigation