Skip to main content
Log in

Optimal Commodity Taxation with Moral Hazard and Unobservable Outcomes

  • Published:
International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The optimal public insurance-taxation scheme is derived for a model with unobservable outcomes. If the government can only observe aggregate commodity expenditures, reimbursement insurance is constrained-efficient. However, two distortions accompany the reimbursement scheme. First, consumers are induced to take (forego) actions which increase (decrease) the likelihood of adverse outcomes (i.e., ex ante moral hazard). Second, reimbursement insurance creates a subsidy distortion (i.e., ex post moral hazard). Ex ante moral hazard calls for taxation (subsidization) of commodities which increase (decrease) the probability of adverse outcomes. The second distortion calls for taxation (subsidization) of commodities which are sufficiently strong complements to (substitutes for) the insured commodity. An example centered on cigarettes and medical insurance is presented.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Arnott, R. and J. E. Stiglitz. (1986). “Moral Hazard and Optimal Commodity Taxation.”Journal of Public Economics 29(1), 1–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arnott, R. and J. E. Stiglitz. (1988). “The Basic Analytics of Moral Hazard.”Scandinavian Journal of Economics 90(3), 383–413.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1976). “Welfare Analysis of Changes in Health Coinsurance Rates.”In R. Rosett (ed.), The Role of Health Insurance in the Health Services Sector. New York: NBER 3–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Balcer, Y. (1980). “Taxation of Externalities: Direct versus Indirect.”Journal of Public Economics 13(1), 121–129.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baltagi, B. H. and J. M. Griffin. (2001). “The Econometrics of Rational Addiction: The Case of Cigarettes.”Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 19(4), 449–454.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. and K. V. Murphy. (1988). “A Theory of Rational Addiction.”Journal of Political Economy 96(4),675–700.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S., M. Grossman and K. V. Murphy. (1991). “Rational Addiction and the Effect of Price on Consumption.”American Economic Review 81(2), 237–241.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S., M. Grossman and K. V. Murphy. (1994). “An Empirical Analysis of Cigarette Addiction.”AmericanEconomic Review 84(3), 396–418.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T. (1988). “Optimal Reimbursement Health Insurance and the Theory of Ramsey Taxation.”Journal of Health Economics 7(4), 321–336.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cameron, S. (2000). “Nicotine Addiction and Cigarette Consumption: A Psycho-Economic Model.”Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 41, 211–219.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chaloupka, F. J. (1991). “Rational Addictive Behavior and Cigarette Smoking.”Journal of Political Economy 99(4), 722–742.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chaloupka, F. J. and K. E. Warner. (2000). “The Economics of Smoking.”In A. J. Culyer and J. P. Newhouse (eds.), Handbook of Health Economics (pp. 1539–1627). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coller, M., G. W. Harrison and M. M. McInnes. (2002). “Evaluating the Tobacco Settlement Damage Awards: Too Much or Not Enough?” American Journal of Public Health 92(6), 984–989.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cook, P. J. and D. A. Graham. (1977). “The Demand for Insurance and Protection: The Case of Irreplaceable Commodities.”Quarterly Journal of Economics 91(1), 143–156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corlett, W. J. and D. C. Hague. (1953-1954). “Complementarity and the Excess Burden of Taxation.”Review of Economic Studies 21(1), 21–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P. A. and J. A. Mirrlees. (1971). “Optimal Taxation and Public Production II: Tax Rules.”American Economic Review 61(3), 261–278.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dionne, G. (1982). “Moral Hazard and State-Dependent Utility Function.”Journal of Risk and Insurance 49(3), 405–422.

    Google Scholar 

  • Escario, J. J. and J. A. Molina. (2001). “Testing for the Rational Addiction Hypothesis in Spanish Tobacco Consumption.”Applied Economic Letters 8, 211–215.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlich, E. and G. S. Becker. (1972). “Market Insurance, Self-Insurance, and Self-Protection.”Journal of Political Economy 80(4), 623–648.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fenn A. J., F. Antonovitz and J. R. Schroeter. (2001). “Cigarettes and Addiction Information: New Evidence in Support of the Rational Addiction Model.”Economic Letters 72, 39–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gruber, J. and B.Köszegi (2001). “Is Addiction 'Rational'? Theory and Evidence.”Quarterly Journal of Economics116, 1261–1303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gruber, J. and S. Mullainathan. (2002). “Do Cigarette Taxes Make Smokers Happier?" NBER Working Paper No. 8872. Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Green, J. and E. Sheshinski. (1976). “Direct versus Indirect Remedies for Externalities.”Journal of Political Economy 84(4), 797–808.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwald, B. C. and J. E. Stiglitz. (1986). “Externalities in Economies with Imperfect Information and Incomplete Markets.”Quarterly Journal of Economics 101(2), 229–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, T. A. (1992). “Cigarette Smoking and Lifetime Medical Expenditures.”Milbank Quarterly 70(1),m 81–125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laux, F. L. (2000). “Addiction as a Market Failure: Using Rational Addiction Results to Justify Tobacco Regulation."Journal of Health Economics 19(4), 421–437.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leu, R. E. and T. Schaub. (1983). “Does Smoking Increase Medical Care Expenditure?” Social Science & Medicine17(23), 1907–1914.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leu, R. E. and T. Schaub. (1984). “Economic Aspects of Smoking.”Effective Health Care 2(3), 111–123.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leu, R. E. and T. Schaub. (1985). “More on the Impact of Smoking on Medical Care Expenditures.”Social Science& Medicine 21(7), 825–827.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manning, W. G., et al. (1989). “The Taxes of Sin: Do Smokers and Drinkers Pay Their Way?” Journal of theAmerican Medical Association 261(11), 1604–1609.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manning, W. G., et al. (1991). The Costs of Poor Health Habits. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard UniversityPress.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, L. S., et al. (1998a). “State Estimates of Medicaid Expenditures Attributable to Cigarette Smoking, FiscalYear 1993.”Public Health Reports 113(2), 140–151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, L. S., et al. (1998b). “State Estimates of Total Medical Expenditures Attributable to Cigarette Smoking,1993.”Public Health Reports 113(5), 447–458.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, V. P. C. Ernst and F. Collin. (1999). “Smoking-Attributable Medical Care Costs in the USA.”Social Science& Medicine 48(3), 375–391.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pauly, M. V. (1968). “The Economics of Moral Hazard: Comment.”American Economic Review 58(3), 531–537.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pauly, M. V. (1974). “Overinsurance and Public Provision of Insurance: The Roles of Moral Hazard and AdverseSelection.”Quarterly Journal of Economics 88(1), 44–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pauly, M. V. (2000). “Insurance Reimbursement.”In A. J. Culyer and J. P. Newhouse (eds.), Handbook of HealthEconomics (pp. 537–560). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramsey, F. P. (1927). “A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation.”Economic Journal 37, 47–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Russo, G. (1989). “An Optimal Cigarette Tax.”Doctoral Dissertation, Northwestern University.

  • Sandmo, A. (1976). “Direct versus Indirect Pigovian Taxation.”European Economic Review 7(4), 337–349.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shavell, S. (1978). “Theoretical Issues in Medical Malpractice.”In S. Rottenberg (ed.), The Economics of MedicalMalpractice (pp. 35–64). Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shavell, S. (1979). “On Moral Hazard and Insurance.”Quarterly Journal of Economics 93(4), 541–562.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. C. (1984). “Self-Command in Practice, in Policy, and in a Theory of Rational Choice.”AmericanEconomic Review 74(2), 1–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. C. (1986a). “Whose Business is Good Behavior?" InW. Knowlton and R. Zechhauser (eds.), AmericanSociety: Public and Private Responsibilities (pp. 153–180). Cambridge, Massachusetts: Ballinger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. C. (1986b). “Economics and Cigarettes.”Preventive Medicine 15, 549–560.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shoven, J. B., J. O. Sundberg and J. P. Bunker. (1989). “The Social Security Cost of Smoking.”In D. A Wise (ed.),The Economics of Aging (pp. 231–250). Chicago: NBER and the University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stoddart, G. L., et al. (1986). “Tobacco Taxes and Health Care Costs: Do Canadian Smokers Pay their Way?"Journal of Health Economics 5(1), 63–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Suranovic, S. M., R. S. Goldfarb and T. C. Leonard. (1999). “An Economic Theory of Cigarette Addiction."Journal of Health Economics 18, 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (1990). “Do Smokers Underestimate Risks?” Journal of Political Economy 98(6) 1253–1269.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (1991). “Age Variation in Risk Perceptions and Smoking Decisions.”Review of Economics andStatistics 73(4), 577–588.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (1992). Smoking: Making the Risky Decisions. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (1995). “Cigarette Taxation and the Social Consequences of Smoking.”In J. M. Poterba (ed.), TaxPolicy and the Economy (pp. 51–101). Cambridge, Massachusetts: NBER and the MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (1999a). “The Government Composition of the Insurance Costs of Smoking.”Journal of Law andEconomics 42(2), 575–609.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (1999b). “Public Perception of Smoking Risks.”In C. Jeanrenaud and N. Soguel (eds.), Valuing the Cost of Smoking: Assessment Methods, Risk Perception and Policy Options (pp. 151–164). Boston: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (2002). Smoked-Filled Rooms: A Postmortem on the Tobacco Deal. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zeckhauser, R. (1970). “Medical Insurance:ACase Study of the Tradeoff between Risk Spreading and Appropriate Incentives.”Journal of Economic Theory 2(1), 10–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, X., et al. (1999). “Cost of Smoking to the Medicare Program, 1993.”Health Care Financing Review 20(4), 179–196.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zweifel, P. and F. Breyer. (1997). Health Economics. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zweifel, P. and W. G. Manning. (2000). “Moral Hazard and Consumer Incentives in Health Care.”In A. J. Culyerand J. P. Newhouse (eds.), Handbook of Health Economics (pp. 409–459). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Russo, G. Optimal Commodity Taxation with Moral Hazard and Unobservable Outcomes. International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics 3, 53–71 (2003). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1023272032586

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1023272032586

Navigation