Skip to main content
Log in

Analysis of strategies for substitutable and complementary products in a two-levels fuzzy supply chain system

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Operational Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, the pricing competition models have been studied between two substitutable and one complementary products in a two-echelon fuzzy supply chain system. Here, three manufacturers separately (one each) produce and sell their products through a common retailer in the cooperative and non-cooperative markets. The demand for each product depends linearly on the products’ prices. Here, manufacturing costs, base demands and price elasticity are characterized as fuzzy parameters. The closed-form expressions of optimal wholesale and retail pricing decisions have been derived for four different market situations under game theory to maximize the expected profit function of each participant of the supply chain. Sharing of profits under co-operation mechanism amongst the manufacturers and retailer in different proportions are presented numerically for the fuzzy model. As particular cases, the optimal pricing decisions have been derived for two substitutable products or two complementary products separately and the results of previous investigators are presented. In addition, the traditional deterministic version of the fuzzy problem is numerically solved. The results of fuzzy and crisp models are presented and compared. Finally, the problem is illustrated with some numerical data for four market situations, sensitivity analyses are performed and management decisions are explored. The products’ demands and supply chain profits are graphically presented for different price elasticity of the substitutable and complementary products.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aust G, Buscher U (2016) Game theoretic analysis of pricing and vertical cooperative advertising of a retailer-duopoly with a common manufacturer. Cent Eur J Oper Res 24(1):127–147

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi SC (1991) Price competition in a channel structure with a common retailer. Mark Sci 10(4):271–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dang J-F, Hong I-H, Lin J-M (2014) The cournot production game with multiple firms under an ambiguous decision environment. Inf Sci 266:186–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elyasi M, Khoshalhan F, Khanmirzaee M (2014) Modified economic order quantity (EOQ) model for items with imperfect quality: game-theoretical approaches. Int J Ind Eng Comput 5(2):211

    Google Scholar 

  • Esmaeili M, Aryanezhad M-B, Zeephongsekul P (2009) A game theory approach in seller–buyer supply chain. Eur J Oper Res 195(2):442–448

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esmaeilzadeh A, Taleizadeh AA (2016) Pricing in a two-echelon supply chain with different market powers: game theory approaches. J Ind Eng Int 12(1):119–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giri B, Sharma S (2014) Manufacturer’s pricing strategy in a two-level supply chain with competing retailers and advertising cost dependent demand. Econ Modell 38:102–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giri RN, Mondal SK, Maiti M (2016) Analysis of pricing decision for substitutable and complementary products with a common retailer. Pac Sci Rev A Nat Sci Eng 18(3):190–202

    Google Scholar 

  • Giri RN, Mondal SK, Maiti M (2017) Bundle pricing strategies for two complementary products with different channel powers. Ann Oper Res. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-017-2632-y

  • Gupta S, Loulou R (1998) Process innovation, product differentiation, and channel structure: strategic incentives in a duopoly. Mark Sci 17(4):301–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang D, Zhou H, Zhao Q-H (2011) A competitive multiple-product newsboy problem with partial product substitution. Omega 39(3):302–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang H, Ke H (2017) Pricing decision problem for substitutable products based on uncertainty theory. J Intell Manuf 28(3):503–514

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khamseh AA, Soleimani F, Naderi B (2014) Pricing decisions for complementary products with firm’s different market powers in fuzzy environments. J Intell Fuzzy Syst 27(5):2327–2340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lau AHL, Lau H-S (2003) Effects of a demand-curve’s shape on the optimal solutions of a multi-echelon inventory/pricing model. Eur J Oper Res 147(3):530–548

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li B-X, Zhou Y-W, Li J-Z, Zhou S-P (2013) Contract choice game of supply chain competition at both manufacturer and retailer levels. Int J Prod Econ 143(1):188–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu B, Liu Y-K (2002) Expected value of fuzzy variable and fuzzy expected value models. IEEE Trans Fuzzy Syst 10(4):445–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu Y-K, Liu B (2003) Expected value operator of random fuzzy variable and random fuzzy expected value models. Int J Uncertain Fuzziness Knowl Based Syst 11(02):195–215

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maity K, Maiti M (2007) Possibility and necessity constraints and their defuzzification—a multi-item production-inventory scenario via optimal control theory. Eur J Oper Res 177(2):882–896

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGuire TW, Staelin R (2008) An industry equilibrium analysis of downstream vertical integration. Mark Sci 27(1):115–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mukhopadhyay SK, Yue X, Zhu X (2011) A stackelberg model of pricing of complementary goods under information asymmetry. Int J Prod Econ 134(2):424–433

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nahmias S (1978) Fuzzy variables. Fuzzy Sets Syst 1(2):97–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parlar M (1988) Game theoretic analysis of the substitutable product inventory problem with random demands. Naval Res Logist 35(3):397–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinha S, Sarmah S (2010) Coordination and price competition in a duopoly common retailer supply chain. Comput Ind Eng 59(2):280–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soleimani F (2016) Optimal pricing decisions in a fuzzy dual-channel supply chain. Soft Comput 20(2):689–696

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei J, Zhao J (2013) Reverse channel decisions for a fuzzy closed-loop supply chain. Appl Math Modell 37(3):1502–1513

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei J, Zhao J (2015) Pricing and remanufacturing decisions in two competing supply chains. Int J Prod Res 53(1):258–278

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei J, Zhao J (2016) Pricing decisions for substitutable products with horizontal and vertical competition in fuzzy environments. Ann Oper Res 242(02):505–528

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei J, Zhao J, Li Y (2013) Pricing decisions for complementary products with firms’ different market powers. Eur J Oper Res 224(3):507–519

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yan R, Pei Z (2011) Information asymmetry, pricing strategy and firm’s performance in the retailer-multi-channel manufacturer supply chain. J Bus Res 64(4):377–384

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yue D, You F (2014) Game-theoretic modeling and optimization of multi-echelon supply chain design and operation under stackelberg game and market equilibrium. Comput Chem Eng 71:347–361

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao J, Liu W, Wei J (2013) Competition under manufacturer service and price in fuzzy environments. Knowl Based Syst 50:121–133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao J, Tang W, Wei J (2012a) Pricing decision for substitutable products with retail competition in a fuzzy environment. Int J Prod Econ 135(1):144–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao J, Tang W, Zhao R, Wei J (2012b) Pricing decisions for substitutable products with a common retailer in fuzzy environments. Eur J Oper Res 216(2):409–419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao J, Wang L (2015) Pricing and retail service decisions in fuzzy uncertainty environments. Appl Math Comput 250:580–592

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao J, Wei J, Li Y (2014) Pricing decisions for substitutable products in a two-echelon supply chain with firms? Different channel powers. Int J Prod Econ 153:243–252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao R, Tang W, Yun H (2006) Random fuzzy renewal process. Eur J Oper Res 169(1):189–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The first author is gratefully to University Grants Commission (UGC, India) for partially financial support to continue this research work by Innovative Research Project Grants (Ref. No. VU/Innovative/Sc/03/2015).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Raghu Nandan Giri.

Appendices

Appendix 1

The expected profit of the supply chain is given by

$$\begin{aligned} E\big [{\widetilde{\pi }}_c\big ]=\, & {} E\big [\big (s_1-{\tilde{c}}_1\big )\big (\tilde{a_1}-{\tilde{\beta }} s_1+\tau {\tilde{\beta }} s_2-\theta _1 {\tilde{\beta }} s_3\big )+\big (s_2-{\tilde{c}}_2\big )\big (\tilde{a_2}+\tau {\tilde{\beta }} s_1-{\tilde{\beta }} s_2-\theta _2 {\tilde{\beta }} s_3\big )\nonumber \\&+\big (s_3-{\tilde{c}}_3\big )\big (\tilde{a_3}-\theta _1 {\tilde{\beta }} s_1-\theta _2 {\tilde{\beta }} s_2-{\tilde{\beta }} s_3\big )\big ]\nonumber \\=\, & {} \frac{1}{2}\int _{0}^{1}\big \{\big [\big (s_1-{\tilde{c}}_1\big )\big (\tilde{a_1}-{\tilde{\beta }} s_1+\tau {\tilde{\beta }} s_2-\theta _1 {\tilde{\beta }} s_3\big )\big ]_{\alpha }^{R}+\big [\big (s_1-\tilde{c_1}\big )\big (\tilde{a_1}-{\tilde{\beta }} s_1+\tau {\tilde{\beta }} s_2-\theta _1 {\tilde{\beta }} s_3\big )\big ]_{\alpha }^{L}\nonumber \\&+\big [\big (s_2-{\tilde{c}}_2\big )\big (\tilde{a_2}+\tau {\tilde{\beta }} s_1-{\tilde{\beta }} s_2-\theta _2 {\tilde{\beta }} s_3\big )\big ]_{\alpha }^{R}+\big [\big (s_2-{\tilde{c}}_2\big )\big (\tilde{a_2}+\tau {\tilde{\beta }} s_1-{\tilde{\beta }} s_2-\theta _2 {\tilde{\beta }} s_3\big )\big ]_{\alpha }^{L}\nonumber \\&+\big [\big (s_3-{\tilde{c}}_3\big )\big (\tilde{a_3}-\theta _1 {\tilde{\beta }} s_1-\theta _2 {\tilde{\beta }} s_2-{\tilde{\beta }} s_3\big )\big ]_{\alpha }^{R}+\big [\big (s_3-{\tilde{c}}_3\big )\big (\tilde{a_3}-\theta _1 {\tilde{\beta }} s_1-\theta _2 {\tilde{\beta }} s_2-{\tilde{\beta }} s_3\big )\big ]_{\alpha }^{L}\big \}d\alpha \nonumber \\=\, & {} \frac{1}{2}\int _{0}^{1}\big \{\big (s_1-{\tilde{c}}_{1\alpha }^{L}\big )\big ({\tilde{a}}_{1\alpha }^{R}-{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L} s_1+\tau {\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R} s_2-\theta _1 {\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L} s_3\big )+\big [\big (s_1-{\tilde{c}}_{1\alpha }^{R}\big )\big ({\tilde{a}}_{1\alpha }^{L}-{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R} s_1+\tau {\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L} s_2\nonumber \\&-\theta _1 {\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R} s_3\big )\big ]+\big (s_2-{\tilde{c}}_{2\alpha }^{L}\big )\big ({\tilde{a}}_{2\alpha }^{R}+\tau {\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R} s_1-{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L} s_2-\theta _2 {\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L} s_3\big )+\big (s_2-{\tilde{c}}_{2\alpha }^{R}\big )\big ({\tilde{a}}_{2\alpha }^{L}+\tau {\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L} s_1\nonumber \\&-{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R} s_2-\theta _2 {\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R} s_3\big )+\big (s_3-{\tilde{c}}_{3\alpha }^{L}\big )\big ({\tilde{a}}_{3\alpha }^{R}-\theta _1 {\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L} s_1-\theta _2 {\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L} s_2-{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L} s_3\big )\nonumber \\&+\big (s_3-{\tilde{c}}_{3\alpha }^{R}\big )\big ({\tilde{a}}_{3\alpha }^{L}-\theta _1 {\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R} s_1-\theta _2 {\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R} s_2-{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R} s_3\big )\big \}d\alpha \nonumber \\=\, & {} \frac{1}{2}\int _{0}^{1}\big \{-\big ({\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}+{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}\big )s_1^2-\big ({\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}+{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}\big )s_2^2-\big ({\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}+{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}\big )s_3^2+2\tau \big ({\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}+{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}\big )s_1s_2\nonumber \\&-2\theta _1 \big ({\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}+{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}\big )s_1s_3-2\theta _2\big ({\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}+{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}\big )s_2s_3+ \big [\big ({\tilde{a}}_{1\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{a}}_{1\alpha }^{L}\big )+\big ({\tilde{c}}_{1\alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}+{\tilde{c}}_{1\alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}\big )\nonumber \\&-\tau \big ({\tilde{c}}_{2\alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{2\alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}\big )+ \theta _1 \big ({\tilde{c}}_{3\alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}+{\tilde{c}}_{3\alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}\big )\big ]s_1 +\big [\big ({\tilde{a}}_{2\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{a}}_{2\alpha }^{L}\big )-\tau \big ({\tilde{c}}_{1\alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{1\alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}\big )\nonumber \\&+\big ({\tilde{c}}_{2\alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}+{\tilde{c}}_{2\alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}\big )+ \theta _2 \big ({\tilde{c}}_{3\alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}+{\tilde{c}}_{3\alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}\big )\big ]s_2+\big [\big ({\tilde{a}}_{3\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{a}}_{3\alpha }^{L}\big )+\theta _1 \big ({\tilde{c}}_{1\alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}+{\tilde{c}}_{1\alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}\big )\nonumber \\&+\theta _2 \big ({\tilde{c}}_{2\alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}+{\tilde{c}}_{2\alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}\big )+\big ({\tilde{c}}_{3\alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}+{\tilde{c}}_{3\alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}\big )\big ]s_3-\big [\big ({\tilde{c}}_{1\alpha }^{L}{\tilde{a}}_{1\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{1\alpha }^{R}{\tilde{a}}_{1\alpha }^{L}\big )\nonumber \\&+ \big ({\tilde{c}}_{2\alpha }^{L}{\tilde{a}}_{2\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{2\alpha }^{R}{\tilde{a}}_{2\alpha }^{L}\big )+\big ({\tilde{c}}_{3\alpha }^{L}{\tilde{a}}_{3\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{3\alpha }^{R}{\tilde{a}}_{3\alpha }^{L}\big )\big ]\big \}d\alpha \nonumber \\=\, & {} -E\big [{\tilde{\beta }}\big ]s_1^2-E\big [{\tilde{\beta }}\big ]s_2^2-E\big [{\tilde{\beta }}\big ]s_3^2+2\tau E\big [{\tilde{\beta }}\big ]s_1s_2-2\theta _1 E\big [{\tilde{\beta }}\big ]s_1s_3-2\theta _2 E\big [{\tilde{\beta }}\big ]s_2s_3\nonumber \\&+\big (E\big [{\tilde{a}}_{1}\big ]+E\big [{\tilde{c}}_{1}{\tilde{\beta }}\big ]+\theta _1 E\big [{\tilde{c}}_{3}{\tilde{\beta }}\big ]\big )s_1+\big (E\big [{\tilde{a}}_{2}\big ]+E\big [{\tilde{c}}_{2}{\tilde{\beta }}\big ]+\theta _2 E\big [{\tilde{c}}_{3}{\tilde{\beta }}\big ]\big )s_2+\big (E\big [{\tilde{a}}_{3}\big ]\nonumber \\&+\theta _1 E\big [{\tilde{c}}_{1}{\tilde{\beta }}\big ]+\theta _2 E\big [{\tilde{c}}_{2}{\tilde{\beta }}\big ]+E\big [{\tilde{c}}_{3}{\tilde{\beta }}\big ]\big )s_3-\frac{\tau }{2}\sum _{i=1}^{2}\left[ \int _0^1\left( {\tilde{c}}_{i \alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{i \alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}\right) d\alpha \right] s_{(3-i)}\nonumber \\&-\frac{1}{2}\sum _{j=1}^3\int _0^1\left( {\tilde{c}}_{j \alpha }^{L}{\tilde{a}}_{j\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{j \alpha }^{R}{\tilde{a}}_{j \alpha }^{L}\right) d\alpha \end{aligned}$$
(20)

The first and second order partial diff. of Eq. (20) w. r. to \(s_1\), \(s_2\) and \(s_3\) are as follows

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial E\left[ {\widetilde{\pi }}_c\right] }{\partial s_1}=\, & {} -2E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] s_1+2\tau E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] s_2-2\theta _1E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] s_3+E\left[ {\tilde{a}}_{1}\right] +E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{1}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] +\theta _1 E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{3}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] -\frac{\tau }{2}\int _0^1\left( {\tilde{c}}_{2 \alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{2 \alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}\right) d\alpha ,\\ \frac{\partial E\left[ {\widetilde{\pi }}_c\right] }{\partial s_2}=\, & {} 2\tau E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] s_1-2E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] s_2-2\theta _2 E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] s_3+E\left[ {\tilde{a}}_{2}\right] +E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{2}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] +\theta _2 E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{3}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] -\frac{\tau }{2}\int _0^1\left( {\tilde{c}}_{1 \alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{1 \alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}\right) d\alpha ,\\ \frac{\partial E\left[ {\widetilde{\pi }}_c\right] }{\partial s_3}= \,& {} -2\theta _1E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] s_1-2\theta _2E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] s_2-2E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] s_3+E\left[ {\tilde{a}}_{3}\right] +\theta _1 E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{1}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] +\theta _2 E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{2}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] +E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{3}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] ,\\ \frac{\partial ^2 E\left[ {\widetilde{\pi }}_c\right] }{\partial s^2_1}=\, & {} -2E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] ,\frac{\partial ^2 E\left[ {\widetilde{\pi }}_c\right] }{\partial s_2 \partial s_1}=2\tau E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] ,\frac{\partial ^2 E\left[ {\widetilde{\pi }}_c\right] }{\partial s_3 \partial s_1}=-2\theta _1E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] ,\frac{\partial ^2 E\left[ {\widetilde{\pi }}_c\right] }{\partial s_1 \partial s_2}=2\tau E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] ,\frac{\partial ^2 E\left[ {\widetilde{\pi }}_c\right] }{\partial s^2_2}=-2E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] ,\\ \frac{\partial ^2 E\left[ {\widetilde{\pi }}_c\right] }{\partial s_3 \partial s_2}=\, & {} -2\theta _2E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] ,\frac{\partial ^2 E\left[ {\widetilde{\pi }}_c\right] }{\partial s_1 \partial s_3}=-2\theta _1E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] ,\frac{\partial ^2 E\left[ {\widetilde{\pi }}_c\right] }{\partial s_2 \partial s_3}=-2\theta _2E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] \;{\mathrm{and}}\;\frac{\partial ^2 E\left[ {\widetilde{\pi }}_c\right] }{\partial s^2_3}=-2E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] . \end{aligned}$$

Determinant value of the Hessian matrix |H| is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \left| \begin{array}{lll} -2E[{\tilde{\beta }}] &{} 2\tau E[{\tilde{\beta }}] &{} -2\theta _1 E[{\tilde{\beta }}]\\ 2\tau E[{\tilde{\beta }}] &{} -2E[{\tilde{\beta }}] &{} -2\theta _2 E[{\tilde{\beta }}] \\ -2\theta _1 E[{\tilde{\beta }}] &{} -2\theta _2 E[{\tilde{\beta }}] &{} -2E[{\tilde{\beta }}]\end{array}\right| =8\{E[{\tilde{\beta }}]\}^3(\tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2-1). \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, the profit expression given in Eq. (20) is concave if \(\tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2<1\) and \(\tau ^2<1\).

At the extreme point, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} -2E[{\tilde{\beta }}]s^*_1+2\tau E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s^*_2-2\theta _1 E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s^*_3&=-K_1,\\ \,\,\,\,2\tau E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s^*_1-2E[{\tilde{\beta }}]s^*_2-2\theta _2 E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s^*_3&=-K_2,\\ -2\theta _1 E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s^*_1-2\theta _2 E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s^*_2-2E[{\tilde{\beta }}]s^*_3&=-K_3, \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(21)

where \(K_1=E[{\tilde{a}}_{1}]+E[{\tilde{c}}_{1}{\tilde{\beta }}]+\theta _1 E[{\tilde{c}}_{3}{\tilde{\beta }}]-\frac{\tau }{2}\int _0^1({\tilde{c}}_{2 \alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{2 \alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L})d\alpha\), \(K_2=E[{\tilde{a}}_{2}]+E[{\tilde{c}}_{2}{\tilde{\beta }}]+\theta _2 E[{\tilde{c}}_{3}{\tilde{\beta }}]-\frac{\tau }{2}\int _0^1({\tilde{c}}_{1 \alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{1 \alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L})d\alpha\) and \(K_3=E[{\tilde{a}}_{3}]+\theta _1 E[{\tilde{c}}_{1}{\tilde{\beta }}]+\theta _2 E[{\tilde{c}}_{2}{\tilde{\beta }}]+E[{\tilde{c}}_{3}{\tilde{\beta }}].\)

Solving the system of linear Eqs. given in (21), we have

$$\begin{aligned} s^*_1=-\frac{(1-\theta _2^2)K_1+(\tau +\theta _1\theta _2)K_2-(\theta _1+\tau \theta _2)K_3}{2E[{\tilde{\beta }}](\tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2-1)} \end{aligned}$$
(22)
$$\begin{aligned} s^*_2=-\frac{(\tau +\theta _1\theta _2)K_1+(1-\theta _1^2)K_2-(\theta _2+\tau \theta _1)K_3}{2E[{\tilde{\beta }}](\tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2-1)} \end{aligned}$$
(23)
$$\begin{aligned} s^*_3=\frac{(\theta _1+\tau \theta _2)K_1+(\theta _2+\tau \theta _1)K_2-(1-\tau ^2)K_3}{2E[{\tilde{\beta }}](\tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2-1)} \end{aligned}$$
(24)

From the constraint \({{\textit{Pos}}}(\{\tilde{a_1}\ge {\tilde{\beta }} s^*_1-\tau {\tilde{\beta }} s^*_2+\theta _1{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_3\})>\eta _1\) and using Definitions 3 and 4, we have

$$\begin{aligned} {\tilde{a}}^{R}_{1\eta _1}>{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_1-\tau {\tilde{\beta }}^{R}_{\eta _1} s^*_2+\theta _1{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_3. \end{aligned}$$

Similarly, from the constraints \({{\textit{Pos}}}(\{\tilde{a_2}\ge -\tau {\tilde{\beta }} s^*_1 +{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_2+\theta _2{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_3\})>\eta _1\), \({{\textit{Pos}}}(\{\tilde{a_3}\ge \theta _1{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_1+\theta _2{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_2+{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_3\})>\eta _1\) and \({{\textit{Pos}}}(\{\tilde{c_i} \le s^*_i\})>\eta _2,\,i=1,2,3\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} {\tilde{a}}^{R}_{2\eta _1}>-\tau {\tilde{\beta }}^{R}_{\eta _1} s^*_1+{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_2 +\theta _2{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_3,\,\,{\tilde{a}}^{R}_{3\eta _1}>\theta _1{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_1+\theta _2{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_2+{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_3 \text{ and } {\tilde{c}}^{L}_{i\eta _2}<s^*_i,\,i=1,2,3. \end{aligned}$$

Appendix 2

The expected profit of the retailer in the MS approach is

$$\begin{aligned} E[{\widetilde{\pi }}_r]=\, & {} (s_1-p_1)(E[\tilde{a_1}]-E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_1+\tau E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_2-\theta _1 E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_3)+(s_2-p_2)(E[\tilde{a_2}]+\tau E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_1\nonumber \\&-E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_2-\theta _2 E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_3)+(s_3-p_3)(E[\tilde{a_3}]-\theta _1 E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_1-\theta _2 E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_2-E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_3) \end{aligned}$$
(25)

Proceeding as “Appendix 1”, retailer’s expected profit expression in the MS approach is concave if

$$\begin{aligned} \tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2<1 \text{ and } \tau ^2<1 \end{aligned}$$

and the retailer’s optimal pricing decisions become

$$\begin{aligned} s^*_1=\frac{p_1}{2}-\frac{(1-\theta _2^2)E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+(\tau +\theta _1\theta _2)E[{\tilde{a}}_2]-(\theta _1+\tau \theta _2)E[{\tilde{a}}_3]}{2E[{\tilde{\beta }}](\tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2-1)} \end{aligned}$$
(26)
$$\begin{aligned} s^*_2=\frac{p_2}{2}-\frac{(\tau +\theta _1\theta _2)E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+(1-\theta _1^2)E[{\tilde{a}}_2]-(\theta _2+\tau \theta _1)E[{\tilde{a}}_3]}{2E[{\tilde{\beta }}](\tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2-1)} \end{aligned}$$
(27)
$$\begin{aligned} s^*_3=\frac{p_3}{2}+\frac{(\theta _1+\tau \theta _2)E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+(\theta _2+\tau \theta _1)E[{\tilde{a}}_2]-(1-\tau ^2)E[{\tilde{a}}_3]}{2E[{\tilde{\beta }}](\tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2-1)} \end{aligned}$$
(28)

From the constraints \({{\textit{Pos}}}(\{\tilde{a_1}\ge {\tilde{\beta }} s^*_1-\tau {\tilde{\beta }} s^*_2+\theta _1{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_3\})>\eta _1\), \({{\textit{Pos}}}(\{\tilde{a_2}\ge -\tau {\tilde{\beta }} s^*_1 +{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_2+\theta _2{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_3\})>\eta _1\), \({{\textit{Pos}}}(\{\tilde{a_3}\ge \theta _1{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_1+\theta _2{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_2+{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_3\})>\eta _1\) and \(s^*_i > p_i\) (i=1,2,3) as similar as “Appendix 1”, we have

$$\begin{aligned}&{\tilde{a}}^{R}_{1\eta _1}>{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_1-\tau {\tilde{\beta }}^{R}_{\eta _1} s^*_2+\theta _1{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_3,\,\, {\tilde{a}}^{R}_{2\eta _1}>-\tau {\tilde{\beta }}^{R}_{\eta _1} s^*_1+{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_2 +\theta _2{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_3,\,\,{\tilde{a}}^{R}_{3\eta _1}>\theta _1{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_1+\theta _2{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_2+{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_3,\\&E[{\tilde{\beta }}](\tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2-1)p_1+(1-\theta _2^2)E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+(\tau +\theta _1\theta _2)E[{\tilde{a}}_2]>(\theta _1+\tau \theta _2)E[{\tilde{a}}_3],\\&E[{\tilde{\beta }}](\tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2-1)p_2+(\tau +\theta _1\theta _2)E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+(1-\theta _1^2)E[{\tilde{a}}_2]>(\theta _2+\tau \theta _1)E[{\tilde{a}}_3],\\ \text{ and }&E[{\tilde{\beta }}](\tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2-1)p_3+(1-\tau ^2)E[{\tilde{a}}_3]>(\theta _1+\tau \theta _2)E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+(\theta _2+\tau \theta _1)E[{\tilde{a}}_2]. \end{aligned}$$

By substituting the Eqs. (26), (27) and (28) into the Eqs. (4),  (5) and (6), the manufacturers’ expected profits can be expressed as

$$\begin{aligned} E\left[ {\widetilde{\pi }}_{M_1}\right]=\, & {} -\frac{1}{2}E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_1^2+\frac{\tau }{2} E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_1p_2-\frac{\theta _1}{2} E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_1p_3+ \frac{1}{2}\left\{ E\left[ {\tilde{a}}_{1}\right] +E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{1}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] \right\} p_1\nonumber \\&-\frac{\tau }{4}\left[ \int _0^1\left( {\tilde{c}}_{1 \alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{1 \alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}\right) d\alpha \right] p_2+\frac{\theta _1}{2} E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{1}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_3+\frac{E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{1}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] E\left[ {\tilde{a}}_{1}\right] }{2E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] }-\frac{1}{2}\int _0^1\left( {\tilde{c}}_{1 \alpha }^{L}{\tilde{a}}_{1\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{1 \alpha }^{R}{\tilde{a}}_{1 \alpha }^{L}\right) d\alpha \end{aligned}$$
(29)
$$\begin{aligned} E\left[ {\widetilde{\pi }}_{M_2}\right]& {} =\, \frac{\tau }{2} E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_1p_2-\frac{1}{2}E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_2^2-\frac{\theta _2}{2} E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_2p_3-\frac{\tau }{4}\left[ \int _0^1\left( {\tilde{c}}_{2 \alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{2 \alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}\right) d\alpha \right] p_1\nonumber \\&\quad +\frac{1}{2}\left\{ E\left[ {\tilde{a}}_{2}\right] +E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{2}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] \right\} p_2+\frac{\theta _2}{2} E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{2}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_3+\frac{E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{2}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] E\left[ {\tilde{a}}_{2}\right] }{2E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] }-\frac{1}{2}\int _0^1\left( {\tilde{c}}_{2 \alpha }^{L}{\tilde{a}}_{2\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{2 \alpha }^{R}{\tilde{a}}_{2 \alpha }^{L}\right) d\alpha \end{aligned}$$
(30)
$$\begin{aligned} E\left[ {\widetilde{\pi }}_{M_3}\right]=\, & {} -\frac{1}{2}\theta _1 E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_1p_3-\frac{1}{2}\theta _2 E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_2p_3- \frac{1}{2}E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_3^2+\frac{\theta _1}{2} E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{3}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_1+\frac{\theta _2}{2} E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{3}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_2\nonumber \\&+\frac{1}{2}\left\{ E\left[ {\tilde{a}}_{3}\right] +E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{3}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] \right\} p_3+\frac{E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{3}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] E\left[ {\tilde{a}}_{3}\right] }{2E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] }-\frac{1}{2}\int _0^1\left( {\tilde{c}}_{3 \alpha }^{L}{\tilde{a}}_{3\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{3 \alpha }^{R}{\tilde{a}}_{3\alpha }^{L}\right) d\alpha \end{aligned}$$
(31)

The first and second order partial diff. of Eq. (29) w. r. to \(p_1\) are as follows

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial E[{\widetilde{\pi }}_{M_1}]}{\partial p_1}=-E[{\tilde{\beta }}] p_1+\frac{\tau }{2}E[{\tilde{\beta }}]p_2-\frac{\theta _1}{2}E[{\tilde{\beta }}]p_3+\frac{1}{2}(E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+E[{\tilde{\beta }}{\tilde{c}}_1]),\,\,and\,\,\frac{ \partial ^2 E[{\widetilde{\pi }}_{M_1}]}{\partial p^2_1}=-E[{\tilde{\beta }}]<0 \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, the manufacturer’s (\(M_1\)) profit expression in MS approach is concave as \(E[{\tilde{\beta }}]>0\) and at the extreme point, we have

$$\begin{aligned} -E[{\tilde{\beta }}] p^*_1+\frac{\tau }{2}E[{\tilde{\beta }}]p^*_2-\frac{\theta _1}{2}E[{\tilde{\beta }}]p^*_3=-\frac{1}{2}(E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+E[{\tilde{\beta }}{\tilde{c}}_1]). \end{aligned}$$
(32)

Similarly, it can be shown that manufacturers’ (\(M_2\) and \(M_3\)) profit expressions for MS approach are also concave and at the extreme point they become

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\tau }{2}E[{\tilde{\beta }}]p^*_1-E[{\tilde{\beta }}] p^*_2-\frac{\theta _2}{2}E[{\tilde{\beta }}]p^*_3=\, & {} -\frac{1}{2}(E[{\tilde{a}}_2]+E[{\tilde{\beta }}{\tilde{c}}_2]) \end{aligned}$$
(33)
$$\begin{aligned} -\frac{\theta _1}{2}E[{\tilde{\beta }}] p^*_1-\frac{\theta _2}{2}E[{\tilde{\beta }}]p^*_2-E[{\tilde{\beta }}] p^*_3=\, & {} -\frac{1}{2}(E[{\tilde{a}}_3]+E[{\tilde{\beta }}{\tilde{c}}_3]) \end{aligned}$$
(34)

Solving Eqs. (32), (33) and  (34), we have

$$\begin{aligned} p^*_1=\, & {} -\frac{(4-\theta _2^2)(E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+E[{\tilde{\beta }}{\tilde{c}}_1])+(2\tau +\theta _1\theta _2)(E[{\tilde{a}}_2]+E[{\tilde{\beta }}{\tilde{c}}_2])-(2\theta _1+\tau \theta _2)(E[{\tilde{a}}_3]+E[{\tilde{\beta }}{\tilde{c}}_3])}{2E[{\tilde{\beta }}](\tau ^2+\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2-4)} \end{aligned}$$
(35)
$$\begin{aligned} p^*_2=\, & {} -\frac{(2\tau +\theta _1\theta _2)(E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+E[{\tilde{\beta }}{\tilde{c}}_1])+(4-\theta _1^2)(E[{\tilde{a}}_2]+E[{\tilde{\beta }}{\tilde{c}}_2])-(2\theta _2+\tau \theta _1)(E[{\tilde{a}}_3]+E[{\tilde{\beta }}{\tilde{c}}_3])}{2E[{\tilde{\beta }}](\tau ^2+\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2-4)}\end{aligned}$$
(36)
$$\begin{aligned} p^*_3=\, & {} \frac{(2\theta _1+\tau \theta _2)(E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+E[{\tilde{\beta }}{\tilde{c}}_1])+(2\theta _2+\tau \theta _1)(E[{\tilde{a}}_2]+E[{\tilde{\beta }}{\tilde{c}}_2])-(4-\tau ^2)(E[{\tilde{a}}_3]+E[{\tilde{\beta }}{\tilde{c}}_3])}{2E[{\tilde{\beta }}](\tau ^2+\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2-4)} \end{aligned}$$
(37)

From the constraints \({{\textit{Pos}}}(\{\tilde{c_i} \le p^*_i\})>\eta _2,\,i=1,2,3\), we have \({\tilde{c}}^{L}_{i\eta _2}<p^*_i,\,i=1,2,3.\)

Appendix 3

The expected profit of the manufacturer \(M_1\) is

$$\begin{aligned} E\left[ {\widetilde{\pi }}_{M_1}\right]= & {} -E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_1^2+\tau E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_1p_2-\theta _1 E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_1p_3+ \left\{ E\left[ {\tilde{a}}_{1}\right] -\left( m_1-\tau m_2+ \theta _1 m_3\right) E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] \right. \nonumber \\&\left. +\,E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{1}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] \right\} p_1-\frac{\tau }{2}\left[ \int _0^1\left( {\tilde{c}}_{1 \alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{1 \alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}\right) d\alpha \right] p_2+\theta _1 E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{1}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_3+E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{1}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] m_1\nonumber \\&+\theta _1 E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_{1}{\tilde{\beta }}\right] m_3-\frac{\tau m_2}{2}\left[ \int _0^1\left( {\tilde{c}}_{1 \alpha }^{L}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{1 \alpha }^{R}{\tilde{\beta }}_{\alpha }^{L}\right) d\alpha \right] -\frac{1}{2}\int _0^1\left( {\tilde{c}}_{1 \alpha }^{L}{\tilde{a}}_{1\alpha }^{R}+{\tilde{c}}_{1 \alpha }^{R}{\tilde{a}}_{1 \alpha }^{L}\right) d\alpha \end{aligned}$$
(38)

The first and second order partial diff. of Eq. (38) w. r. to \(p_1\) are as follows

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial E\left[ {\widetilde{\pi }}_{M_1}\right] }{\partial p_1}=E\left[ {\tilde{a}}_1\right] -E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] (p_1+m_1)+\tau E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] (p_2+m_2)-\theta _1E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] (p_3+m_3)-E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] p_1+E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}{\tilde{c}}_1\right] \end{aligned}$$

and \(\frac{ \partial ^2 E[{\widetilde{\pi }}_{M_1}]}{\partial p^2_1}=-2E[{\tilde{\beta }}]<0.\) Therefore, the manufacturer’s (\(M_1\)) expected profit expression in RS approach is concave as \(E[{\tilde{\beta }}]>0\) and at the extreme point, optimum pricing decisions of \(M_1\) is

$$\begin{aligned} p^*_1=\frac{E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+E[{\tilde{\beta }}{\tilde{c}}_1]}{E[{\tilde{\beta }}]}-s_1+\tau s_2-\theta _1 s_3. \end{aligned}$$
(39)

Similarly, we can show that manufacturers’ (\(M_2\) and \(M_3\)) expected profit expressions in RS approach are concave as \(E[{\tilde{\beta }}]>0\) and optimum pricing decisions for \(M_2\) and \(M_3\) are respectively given by

$$\begin{aligned} p^*_2= & {} \frac{E[{\tilde{a}}_2]+E[{\tilde{\beta }}{\tilde{c}}_2]}{E[{\tilde{\beta }}]}+\tau s_1- s_2-\theta _2 s_3 \end{aligned}$$
(40)
$$\begin{aligned} p^*_3= & {} \frac{E[{\tilde{a}}_3]+E[{\tilde{\beta }}{\tilde{c}}_3]}{E[{\tilde{\beta }}]}-\theta _1 s_1-\theta _2 s_2- s_3 \end{aligned}$$
(41)

From the constraints \({{\textit{Pos}}}(\{\tilde{c_i} \le p^*_i\})>\eta _2,\,i=1,2,3\), we have \({\tilde{c}}^{L}_{i\eta _2}<p^*_i,\,i=1,2,3.\)

The retailer’s expected profit after manufacturers’ optimal decisions in RS approach is given by

$$\begin{aligned} E[{\widetilde{\pi }}_r]= & {} (s_1-p^*_1)(a_1-E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_1+\tau E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_2-\theta _1 E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_3)+(s_2-p^*_2)(a_2 +\tau E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_1-E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_2\nonumber \\&-\theta _2 E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_3) +(s_3-p^*_3)(a_3-\theta _1 E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_1-\theta _2 E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_2-E[{\tilde{\beta }}] s_3) \end{aligned}$$
(42)

The first and second order partial diff. of Eq. (42) w. r. to \(s_1\), \(s_2\) and \(s_3\) are as follows

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial E[{\widetilde{\pi }}_{r}]}{\partial s_1} & {} = -P s_1+Q s_2-R s_3+B_1,\,\,\,\frac{\partial E[{\widetilde{\pi }}_{r}]}{\partial s_2}=Q s_1-S s_2-T s_3+B_2,\\ \frac{\partial E[{\widetilde{\pi }}_{r}]}{\partial s_3}& {} = -R s_1-T s_2-U s_3+B_3,\,\,\frac{\partial ^2 E[{\widetilde{\pi }}_{r}]}{\partial s^2_1}=-P,\,\,\frac{\partial ^2 E[{\widetilde{\pi }}_{r}]}{\partial s_2 \partial s_1}=Q,\,\,\frac{\partial ^2 E[{\widetilde{\pi }}_{r}]}{\partial s_3 \partial s_1}=-R,\\ \frac{\partial ^2 E[{\widetilde{\pi }}_{r}]}{\partial s_1 \partial s_2}& {} = Q,\,\,\frac{\partial ^2 E[{\widetilde{\pi }}_{r}]}{\partial s^2_2}=-S,\,\,\frac{\partial ^2 E[{\widetilde{\pi }}_{r}]}{\partial s_3 \partial s_2}=-T,\,\,\frac{\partial ^2 E[{\widetilde{\pi }}_{r}]}{\partial s_1 \partial s_3}=-R,\,\,\frac{\partial ^2 E[{\widetilde{\pi }}_{r}]}{\partial s_2 \partial s_3}=-T,\,\,\, \frac{\partial ^2 E[{\widetilde{\pi }}_{r}]}{\partial s^2_3}=-U,\\ \text{ where } P& {} = 2E[{\tilde{\beta }}](2+\tau ^2+\theta _1^2),\,\,Q= 2E[{\tilde{\beta }}](3\tau -\theta _1\theta _2),\,\, R=2E[{\tilde{\beta }}](3\theta _1-\tau \theta _2),\,\,\\ S& {}=\, 2E[{\tilde{\beta }}](2+\tau ^2+\theta _2^2),\,\,T=2E[{\tilde{\beta }}](3\theta _2-\tau \theta _1),\,\,U=2E[{\tilde{\beta }}](2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2),\\ B_1& {}= 3E[{\tilde{a}}_1]-2\tau E[{\tilde{a}}_2]+2\theta _1E[{\tilde{a}}_3]+E[{\tilde{c}}_1{\tilde{\beta }}]-\tau E[{\tilde{c}}_2{\tilde{\beta }}]+\theta _1E[{\tilde{c}}_3{\tilde{\beta }}],\,\,\\ B_2& {}=\, 3E[{\tilde{a}}_2]-2\tau E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+2\theta _2E[{\tilde{a}}_3]-\tau E[{\tilde{c}}_1{\tilde{\beta }}]+E[{\tilde{c}}_2{\tilde{\beta }}]+\theta _2E[{\tilde{c}}_3{\tilde{\beta }}],\,\,\\ B_3& {}=\, 3E[{\tilde{a}}_3]+2\theta _1E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+2\theta _2E[{\tilde{a}}_2]+\theta _1E[{\tilde{c}}_1{\tilde{\beta }}]+\theta _2E[{\tilde{c}}_2{\tilde{\beta }}]+E[{\tilde{c}}_3{\tilde{\beta }}]. \end{aligned}$$

The above retailer’s expected profit expression in RS approach is concave if

$$\begin{aligned} \tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2<1\,and\,\tau ^2+\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2<4. \end{aligned}$$

At the extreme point, we have

$$\begin{aligned} P s^*_1-Q s^*_2+R s^*_3=B_1,\,\,\,-Q s^*_1+S s^*_2+T s^*_3=B_2\,\,\,{\mathrm{and}}\,\,\,R s^*_1+T s^*_2+U s^*_3=B_3 \end{aligned}$$
(43)

Solving the system of linear Eqs. given in (43), we have

$$\begin{aligned} s^*_1= \,& {} \frac{B_1(T^2-SU)-B_2(RT+QU)+B_3(QT+RS)}{(UQ^2+2QRT+SR^2+PT^2-PSU)}\nonumber \\ s^*_2=\, & {} \frac{-B_1(RT+QU)+B_2(R^2-PU)+B_3(QR+PT)}{(UQ^2+2QRT+SR^2+PT^2-PSU)}\nonumber \\ s^*_3= \,& {} \frac{B_1(QT+RS)+B_2(QR+PT)+B_3(Q^2-PS)}{(UQ^2+2QRT+SR^2+PT^2-PSU)} \end{aligned}$$
(44)

From the constraints \({{\textit{Pos}}}(\{\tilde{a_1}\ge {\tilde{\beta }} s^*_1-\tau {\tilde{\beta }} s^*_2+\theta _1{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_3\})>\eta _1\), \({{\textit{Pos}}}(\{\tilde{a_2}\ge -\tau {\tilde{\beta }} s^*_1 +{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_2+\theta _2{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_3\})>\eta _1\) and \({{\textit{Pos}}}(\{\tilde{a_3}\ge \theta _1{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_1+\theta _2{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_2+{\tilde{\beta }} s^*_3\})>\eta _1\) as similar as “Appendix 1”, we have

$$\begin{aligned} {\tilde{a}}^{R}_{1\eta _1}>{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_1-\tau {\tilde{\beta }}^{R}_{\eta _1} s^*_2+\theta _1{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_3,\,\, {\tilde{a}}^{R}_{2\eta _1}>-\tau {\tilde{\beta }}^{R}_{\eta _1} s^*_1+{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_2 +\theta _2{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_3,\,\,{\tilde{a}}^{R}_{3\eta _1}>\theta _1{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_1+\theta _2{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_2+{\tilde{\beta }}^{L}_{\eta _1} s^*_3. \end{aligned}$$

Appendix 4

The optimum decisions of three manufacturers and one retailer are derived in RS and MS approaches and given in Eqs. (39), (40),  (41), (26), (27) and (28). For Nash-equilibrium strategies, solving these six equations, we have

$$\begin{aligned} p^*_1=\, & {} -\frac{\left( 9-\theta _2^2\right) \left( E\left[ {\tilde{a}}_1\right] +E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_1{\tilde{\beta }}\right] \right) +\left( 3\tau +\theta _1\theta _2\right) \left( E\left[ {\tilde{a}}_2\right] +E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_2{\tilde{\beta }}\right] \right) -\left( 3\theta _1+\tau \theta _2\right) \left( E\left[ {\tilde{a}}_3\right] +E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_3{\tilde{\beta }}\right] \right) }{E\left[ {\tilde{\beta }}\right] \left( 3\tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+3\theta _1^2+3\theta _2^2-27\right) } \end{aligned}$$
(45)
$$\begin{aligned} p^*_2=\, & {} -\frac{\left( 3\tau +\theta _1\theta _2\right) \left( E\left[ {\tilde{a}}_1\right] +E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_1{\tilde{\beta }}\right] \right) +\left( 9-\theta _1^2\right) \left( E\left[ {\tilde{a}}_2\right] +E\left[ {\tilde{c}}_2{\tilde{\beta }}\right] \right) -\left( 3\theta _2+\tau \theta _1\right) \left( E[{\tilde{a}}_3]+E[{\tilde{c}}_3{\tilde{\beta }}]\right) }{E[{\tilde{\beta }}]\left( 3\tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+3\theta _1^2+3\theta _2^2-27\right) }\end{aligned}$$
(46)
$$\begin{aligned} p^*_3=\, & {} \frac{\left( 3\theta _1+\tau \theta _2\right) \left( E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+E[{\tilde{c}}_1{\tilde{\beta }}]\right) +\left( 3\theta _2+\tau \theta _1\right) \left( E[{\tilde{a}}_2]+E[{\tilde{c}}_2{\tilde{\beta }}]\right) -\left( 9-\tau ^2\right) \left( E[{\tilde{a}}_3]+E[{\tilde{c}}_3{\tilde{\beta }}]\right) }{E[{\tilde{\beta }}]\left( 3\tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+3\theta _1^2+3\theta _2^2-27\right) }\end{aligned}$$
(47)
$$\begin{aligned} s^*_1= \,& {} \frac{p^*_1}{2}-\frac{\left( 1-\theta _2^2\right) E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+\left( \tau +\theta _1\theta _2\right) E[{\tilde{a}}_2]-\left( \theta _1+\tau \theta _2\right) E[{\tilde{a}}_3]}{2E[{\tilde{\beta }}]\left( \tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2-1\right) }\end{aligned}$$
(48)
$$\begin{aligned} s^*_2= \,& {} \frac{p^*_2}{2}-\frac{\left( \tau +\theta _1\theta _2\right) E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+\left( 1-\theta _1^2\right) E[{\tilde{a}}_2]-\left( \theta _2+\tau \theta _1\right) E[{\tilde{a}}_3]}{2E[{\tilde{\beta }}]\left( \tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2-1\right) }\end{aligned}$$
(49)
$$\begin{aligned} s^*_3=\, & {} \frac{p^*_3}{2}+\frac{\left( \theta _1+\tau \theta _2\right) E[{\tilde{a}}_1]+\left( \theta _2+\tau \theta _1\right) E[{\tilde{a}}_2]-\left( 1-\tau ^2\right) E[{\tilde{a}}_3]}{2E[{\tilde{\beta }}]\left( \tau ^2+2\tau \theta _1\theta _2+\theta _1^2+\theta _2^2-1\right) } \end{aligned}$$
(50)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Giri, R.N., Mondal, S.K. & Maiti, M. Analysis of strategies for substitutable and complementary products in a two-levels fuzzy supply chain system. Oper Res Int J 21, 485–524 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12351-018-0443-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12351-018-0443-9

Keywords

Navigation