Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Life Satisfaction and Preferences over Economic Growth and Institutional Quality

  • Published:
Journal of Labor Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper demonstrates that institutional factors have differential impacts on subjective well-being of individuals in rich versus poor countries. A lower level of corruption, a more democratic government and better civil rights increase the well-being of individuals in rich countries, whereas an increase in per capita income has no impact. On the contrary, in poor countries the extent of corruption, democracy or civil rights has no influence on happiness, but an increase in per capita income impacts happiness positively. We provide evidence that this stark contrast may be due to the difference of preferences over economic growth and institutional factors.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Sacks, Stevenson and Wolfers (2010) show that average happiness is higher in countries with greater GDP per capita. Stevenson and Wolfers (2013)show that income increases improves life satisfaction without a satiation point.

  2. Previous research documents a positive relationship between economic growth and institutional quality (Rigobon and Rodrik 2005; Dollar and Kraay 2003; Acemoglu and Robinson 2000; Hall and Jones 1999), and between favorable institutional characteristics and life satisfaction (Frey and Stutzer 2000; Veenhoven 2000).

  3. http://www.worldvaluessurvey.org/World Values Survey provides a repeated cross-sectional data set.

  4. Only the countries for which the whole set of country-level variables could be obtained are used in estimation.

  5. We include countries that are available in the World Values Survey. List of the countries is available upon request.

  6. This measures the perceived corruption among public officials and politicians. We constructed our corruption measure by using the average of the country’s corruption score. Averaging does not constitute a problem, since it has been documented that corruption level in a country do not vary much over time (Mauro 1995 and Mocan 2008).

  7. This index measures the real-world rights and freedoms enjoyed by individuals. When the information is missing for a country, we used the index value for that country that is closest in time to the survey year of that country.

  8. Polity IV considers three elements: degree of competition in political participation, institutionalization of constraints on executive power and availability of civil liberties to citizens in daily life and political participation.

  9. The answer is chosen from a scale between one and ten, with “Most dissatisfied” (1) and “Most satisfied” (10).

  10. Individual-level variables considered are individual’s gender, age, income, education level, employment and marital status and the number of children the individual has. Country-level controls include the inflation rate and unemployment rates, carbon dioxide emission per capita and birth rate.

  11. Similar findings are obtained when other life satisfaction categories are considered. Probabilities of being in the higher (lower) life satisfaction categories are positively (negatively) correlated with increases per capita GDP.

  12. Deaton (2008) mentions that these countries are Moldova, Ukraine, Armenia, Belarus, Russia, Bulgaria, Latvia, Estonia, Azerbaijan, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Macedonia, Romania, Estonia, and Slovakia.

  13. Di Tella and MacCulloch (2010) estimate a model where the average happiness level in rich and poor countries is a function of past GDP per capita and the growth rate of GDP. They find that the average life satisfaction in a poor country is positively correlated with both past GDP per capita and GDP growth, but only the level of past GDP in a rich country impacts average happiness.

  14. Theses variables are constructed based on individual’s first and second choice on their country’s national goals. Respondents’ options were 1.A high level of economic growth, 2.Strong defense forces, 3.People have more say about how things are done, 4.Trying to make our cities and countryside more beautiful.

  15. When we use other categories as outcome variables, the marginal effects are not statistically significant.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson J (2000) Why Did the west extend the franchise? democracy, inequality, and growth in historical perspective. Q J Econ 115:1167–1199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S, Robinson J (2001) The colonial origins of comparative development: an empirical investigation. Am Econ Rev 91(5):1369–1401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Di Tella R, MacCulloch R (2004) Inequality and happiness: Are Europeans and Americans different?”. J Public Econ 88:2009–2042

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjørnskov C, Dreher A, Fischer J (2010) Formal institutions and subjective well-being: revisiting the cross-country evidence. Eur J Polit Econ 26(4):419–430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower D, Oswald A (2008) Is well-being U-shaped over the life cycle?”. Soc Sci Med 66(8):1733–1749

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark A, Frijters P, Shields M (2008) Relative income, happiness, and utility: an explanation for the easterlin paradox and other puzzles. J Econ Lit 46(1):95–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton A (2008) Income, health and wellbeing around the world: evidence from the Gallup world poll. J Econ Perspect 22(2):53–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Tella R and R MacCulloch (2010) "Happiness Adaptation to Income beyond 'Basic Needs'." Chap. 8 in International Differences in Well-Being, edited by E.Diener, J. Helliwell, and D. Kahneman, New York: Oxford University Press

  • Di Tella R, MacCulloch R, Oswald A (2003) The macroeconomics of happiness. Rev Econ Stat 85(4):809–827

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Tella R, Haisken-De New J, MacCulloch R (2010) Happiness adaptation to income and to status in an individual panel. J Econ Behav Organ 76(3):834–852

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dollar D, Kraay A (2003) Institutions, trade, and growth. J Monet Econ 50(1):133–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin R (1973) Does money buy happiness?”. Public Interest 30:3–10

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin R (1995) Will raising the incomes of All increase the happiness of All?”. J Econ Behav Organ 27(1):35–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey B, Stutzer A (2000) Happiness, economy and institutions. Econ J 110(466):918–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall R, Jones C (1999) Why Do some countries produce So much more output per worker than others? Q J Econ 114(1):83–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell J, Huang H (2008) How’s your government? international evidence linking good government and well-being. Br J Polit Sci 38:595–619

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maslow A (1943) A theory of human motivation. Psychol Rev 50(4):370–396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mauro P (1995) Corruption and growth. Q J Econ 110:681–712

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Minier J (1998) Democracy and growth: alternative approaches. J Econ Growth 3(3):241–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mocan N (2008) What determines corruption? international evidence from micro data. Econ Inq 46(4):493–510

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mocan N, Rees D (2005) Economic conditions, deterrence and juvenile crime: evidence from micro data. Am Law Econ Rev 7(2):319–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oswald A (1997) Happiness and economic performance. Econ J 107(445):1815–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Papaioannou E, Siourounis G (2008) Democratisation and growth. Econ J 118(532):1520–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rigobon R, Rodrik D (2005) Rule of Law, democracy, openness, and income”. Econ Transit 13(3):533–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sacks D, Stevenson B and Wolfers J (2010) "Subjective Well-Being, Income, Economic Development and Growth." NBER Working Papers no. 16441

  • Stevenson B, Wolfers J (2013) Subjective well-being and income: is there Any evidence of satiation? Am Econ Rev 103(3):598–604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veenhoven R (2000) Freedom and happiness: a comparative study in forty-four nations in the early 1990s. In: Diener E, Suh E (eds) Culture and subjective well being. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Duha T. Altindag.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest

Appendix

Appendix

Table 5 Descriptions and Summary Statistics of All Variables
Table 6 Marginal Effects of All Variables from Ordered Probit Estimation Dependent Variable: Satisfaction with Life
Table 7 Effect of National Income and Institutions on Life Satisfaction in Poor vs. Rich Countries (Sensitivity to the cutoffs)
Table 8 Effect of National Income and Institutions on Life Satisfaction in Poor vs. Rich Countries (Sensitivity to the countries in the sample)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Altindag, D.T., Xu, J. Life Satisfaction and Preferences over Economic Growth and Institutional Quality. J Labor Res 38, 100–121 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-016-9235-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-016-9235-2

Keywords

Navigation