Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Counting the missing poor in pre-industrial societies

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Cliometrica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Under income-differentiated mortality, poverty measures suffer from a selection bias: they do not count the missing poor (i.e., persons who would have been counted as poor provided they did not die prematurely). The Pre-Industrial period being characterized by an evolutionary advantage (i.e., a higher number of surviving children per household) of the non-poor over the poor, one may expect that the missing poor bias is substantial during that period. This paper quantifies the missing poor bias in Pre-Industrial societies, by computing the hypothetical headcount poverty rates that would have prevailed provided the non-poor did not benefit from an evolutionary advantage over the poor. Using data on Pre-Industrial England and France, we show that the sign and size of the missing poor bias are sensitive to the degree of downward social mobility.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Besides the discussion of King’s table (for year 1688), Lindert and Williamson (1982) provide also a critical presentation of other social tables, such as the ones of Joseph Massie (for year 1759) and Patrick Colquhoun (for years 1801–1803). Lindert and Williamson (1983) revisits the social table of Dudley Baxter (for year 1868), and provide a picture of England’s development during two centuries.

  2. Several mechanisms may explain why the rich had, at that time, a higher number of surviving children than the poor. These mechanisms include the various channels through which material living conditions affect mortality and fertility outcomes. Throughout this paper, we will take that evolutionary advantage as given and examine its impact on poverty measurement, without trying to identify the particular mechanisms at work behind this advantage.

  3. See Malthus (1798), chapter 1, pp. 71–72 and chapter 5, p. 93.

  4. Note that other works evaluating the Malthusian doctrine yield mixed results. See Wrigley (1969), Mokyr (1980), Clark (2007), Crafts and Mills (2009) and Cummins (2020).

  5. For instance, while poverty above age 60 is higher in Portugal than in Estonia on the basis of standard headcount poverty rates, the ranking of poverty is reversed once the missing poor are taken into account.

  6. Given that this paper assumes that skills are redistributed randomly in each new cohort, it underestimates the persistence of cumulative selection effects, unlike the present paper.

  7. In a recent work, de la Croix et al. (2019) show that the reproductive success of the middle class exceeded the one of the poor and the very rich classes in Pre-Industrial England.

  8. Campbell (2013) showed that per capita income increased in Italy during its twelfth and thirteenth century commercial revolution, in Holland during its fifteenth and sixteenth century golden age, and in England during the seventeenth and eighteenth century runup to its industrial revolution. During these episodes, expanding trade sustained output and employment growth in the manufacturing and service sectors, developments that were not reflected in real wage data.

  9. The effects of that pattern on family welfare are studied by Horrell et al. (2021).

  10. However, this paper does not address the issue of the transition to the Industrial period (Polak and Williamson 1991). Due to the demographic transition (Lee 2003), our model would have to be amended to account for variations in survival and fertility conditions.

  11. We consider here a closed economy and we abstract from migrations. Abstracting from migrations is a simplification. However, this assumption makes sense for the Pre-Industrial epoch, during which most movements of populations took place within a country rather than between countries (see Wrigley 1969).

  12. We have \({\bar{m}}_{p}=1-m_{p}\).

  13. We have \({\bar{m}}_{n}=1-m_{n}\).

  14. See Caswell (2001), pp. 83–84.

  15. See Caswell (2001), pp. 84–85.

  16. Various mechanisms may explain why \(\mu >1\). On the mortality side, bad material living conditions can lead to higher mortality of the poor because of low quality/quantity of food or lack of health care. On the fertility side, the effects of poverty on fertility may take distinct forms. For instance, poverty may cause physiological stress that reduces fertility. However, it is also possible that humans, like other living beings, react to a poor environment by adopting a particular life history strategy involving a larger number of descendants (r-strategy), which may counterbalance the previous effect. We will not try here to quantify all these effects. Rather, we will take \(\mu\) as given and consider its effect on the measurement of poverty.

  17. On the evolutionary advantage of the rich in Pre-Industrial times, see (Clark 2007).

  18. The headcount poverty rate HC is fully determined by parameters \(\left\{ m_{n},m_{p},\mu \right\}\). Hence the derivative \(\frac{\partial {\rm HC}}{ \partial \mu }\) measures the full effect of a marginal variation of the strength of the evolutionary advantage of the non-poor on the prevalence of poverty in the long-run.

  19. The intuition behind that result goes as follows. If we were considering the size of the population in the long-run, the absolute levels of group-specific fertility rates and survival rates would matter. However, from the perspective of the structure of the population in the long-run, only the relative levels of fertility and survival rates across groups matter. The long-run structure of the population depends on whether one group has a larger number of surviving offspring than another.

  20. It should be stressed that the latter number is higher, but still of a close magnitude to estimates for poverty in the UK around 1820 in Bourguignon and Morrisson (2002) and Ravallion (2016), which lie around 40–45%.

  21. For instance, under a low downward mobility (\(m_{n}=0.100\)), a probability of leaving poverty of 0.186 can replicate a headcount poverty rate of 24.2%, but to reproduce \({\rm HC}=48.2\)%, one needs, under \(m_{n}=0.100\), a lower upward mobility for the poor, \(m_{p}\) being extremely low (0.001).

  22. For the sake of making that point, let us assume that the measures of poverty in Sects. 7 and 8 are comparable. If, for instance, one adopts the intermediate benchmark for poverty in Pre-Industrial England, and compare it with the measure of poverty in Pre-Industrial France (lower bound), one can see that HC is higher in France than in England. However, this may not be the case when considering hypothetical poverty rates \({\rm HC}^{H}\) where all selection biases are neutralized. Under a low downward social mobility, \({\rm HC}^{H}\) is lower in France than in England. Note that such an inversion of the ranking does not occur when a high downward social mobility is assumed (since in that case \({\rm HC}^{H}\) is close to HC in each country).

  23. One limitation of this matrix population model is that it cannot account for potential second-order effects due to interactions between fertility, mortality and intergenerational mobility, because these are modelled as parameters, and not as variables. We leave the exploration of more general models for future research.

  24. For that purpose, it would be useful to study the various mechanisms at work behind the evolutionary advantage of the non-poor over the poor in Pre-Industrial societies, by using the literature in evolutionary anthropology (see Hill and Kaplan 1999; Kaplan et al. 2000).

References

  • Allen RC (2009) The British industrial revolution in global perspective. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Angeles L (2008) GDP per capita or real wages? Making sense on conflicting views on pre-industrial Europe. Explor Econ Hist 45:147–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnett G (1936) Two tracts by Gregory King. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon F, Morrisson C (2002) World distribution among world citizens: 1820–1992. Am Econ Rev 92:727–744

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broadberry SN, Campbell BMS, Klein A, Overton M, van Leeuwen B (2015) British Economic Growth 1270–1870. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell BMS (2013) National incomes and economic growth in pre-industrial Europe: insights from recent research. Quaest Medii Aevi Novae 18:167–96

    Google Scholar 

  • Caswell H (2001) Matrix population models: construction, analysis, and interpretation. Sinauer, Sunderland, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark G (2007) A farewell to alms: a brief economic history of the world. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G (2014) The son also rises: surnames and the history of social mobility. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark G, Cummins N (2015) Malthus to modernity: wealth, status and fertility in England, 1500–1879. J Popul Econ 28:3–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G, Hamilton G (2006) Survival of the richest. The Malthusian mechanism in pre-industrial England. J Econ Hist 66:707–736

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crafts N, Mills T (2009) From Malthus to Solow: how did the Malthusian economy really evolve? J Macroecon 31:68–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cummins N (2020) The micro-evidence for the Malthusian system. France, 1670–1840. Eur Econ Rev 129(C):103544

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Croix D, Schneider E, Weisdorf J (2019) Childlessness, celibacy and net fertility in Pre-Industrial England: the middle-class evolutionary advantage. J Econ Growth 24:223–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Vries J (2008) The industrious revolution: consumer behavior and the household economy. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Foster J, Greer J, Thorbecke E (1984) A class of decomposable poverty measures. Econometrica 52:761–766

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O (2010) The 2008 Laurence R. Klein Lecture—comparative economic development: insights from unified growth theory. Int Econ Rev 51:1–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O (2011) Unified growth theory. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Moav O (2002) Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. Q J Econ 117:1133–1191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Moav O (2005) Natural selection and the evolution of life expectancy. Working Paper, Department of Economics, Brown University, Providence

  • Hill K, Kaplan H (1999) Life history traits in humans: theory and empirical studies. Ann Rev Anthropol 28:397–430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horrell S, Humphries J, Weisdorf J (2021) Family standards of living over the long run, England 1280–1850. Past Present 250:87–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Humphries J, Weisdorf J (2019) Unreal wages? Real income and economic growth in England, 1260–1850. Econ J 129:2867–2887

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Isnard A (1781) Traité des richesses. Londres et Lausanne

  • Kanbur R, Mukherjee D (2007) Premature mortality and poverty measurement. Bull Econ Res 59:339–359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan H, Hill K, Lancaster J, Hurtado M (2000) A theory of human life history evolution: diet, intelligence and longevity. Evol Anthropol 9:156–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee R (2003) The demographic transition. Three centuries of fundamental change. J Econ Perspect 17:167–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lefebvre M, Pestieau P, Ponthiere G (2013) Measuring poverty without the mortality paradox. Soc Choice Welf 40:285–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lefebvre M, Pestieau P, Ponthiere G (2018) FGT old-age poverty measures and the mortality paradox: theory and evidence. Rev Income Wealth 64:428–458

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lefebvre M, Pestieau P, Ponthiere G (2019a) Missing poor and income mobility. J Comp Econ 47:330–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lefebvre M, Pestieau P, Ponthiere G (2019b) Missing poor and income mobility. J Popul Econ 32:621–664

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindert P, Williamson J (1982) Revisiting England’s social tables 1688–1812. Explor Econ Hist 19:385–408

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindert P, Williamson J (1983) Reinterpreting England’s social tables, 1688–1913. Explor Econ Hist 20:94–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malthus T (1798) An essay on the principle of population. St. Paul’s Churchyard, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr J (1980) Malthusian models and Irish history. J Econ Hist 40:159–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morrisson C, Snyder W (2000) The income inequality in France in historical perspective. Eur Rev Econ Hist 4:59–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polak B, Williamson J (1991) Poverty, policy and industrialization. World Bank, Working Paper

  • Ravallion M (2016) The economics of poverty: history, measurement and policy. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sen AK (1976) Poverty: an ordinal approach to measurement. Econometrica 44:219–231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen AK (1998) Mortality as an indicator of economic success and failure. Econ J 108:1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wrigley EA (1969) History and population. Weidenfeld and Nicolson, London

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gregory Ponthiere.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The authors would like to thank Arnaud Deseau, Claude Diebolt, Sylvain Funck, Oded Galor, Gilles Grandjean and two anonymous reviewers, as well as participants of seminar at Université Saint Louis (Brussels), for their comments on this paper. This work was supported by the French National Research Agency Grant ANR-17-EURE-0020, and by the Excellence Initiative of Aix-Marseille University—A*MIDEX.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Proposition 1

Irreducibility prevails when the life cycle graph associated to the matrix admits at least one path from each node and toward each node. This is the case for matrix \({\mathbf {M}}\). As shown in Fig. 2, the life cycle graph associated to our model includes two distinct populations, i.e.,, poor and non-poor, which contribute to each other through the social mobility process, which can go upwards or not for the poor, and downwards or not for the non-poor. Thus each population makes contributions to the other population, implying irreducibility of \({\mathbf {M}}\).

Primitivity arises when there exists a power k such that raising the matrix to that power makes it positive. This is clearly the case for matrix \({\mathbf {M}}\), which is a positive matrix.

1.2 Proof of Proposition 2

Let us characterize eigenvalues of the matrix \({\mathbf {M}}\). We look for solutions for the equation:

$$\begin{aligned} \mathbf {Mw=}\lambda {\mathbf {w}} \end{aligned}$$

where \(\lambda\) is the eigenvalue (a scalar) while \({\mathbf {w}}\) is the associated eigen vector, a vector that makes matrix multiplication and scalar multiplication equivalents. From the definition of the eigen vectors, it follows that:

$$\begin{aligned} \mathbf {Mw-}\lambda \mathbf {w}= & {} \mathbf {0} \\ \left( \mathbf {M-}\lambda {\mathbf {I}}\right) {\mathbf {w}}= & {} {\mathbf {0}} \end{aligned}$$

Nonzero solutions require \(\left( \mathbf {M-}\lambda {\mathbf {I}}\right)\) to be a singular matrix, that is, that it has a zero determinant.

Hence eigenvalues are solutions to:

$$\begin{aligned} \det \left( \begin{array}{cc} f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}-\lambda &{} f_{n}s_{n}m_{n} \\ f_{p}s_{p}m_{p} &{} f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}-\lambda \end{array} \right) =0 \end{aligned}$$

Therefore we have:

$$\begin{aligned} \left( f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}-\lambda \right) \left( f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}} _{n}-\lambda \right) -f_{n}s_{n}m_{n}f_{p}s_{p}m_{p}=0 \end{aligned}$$

Hence, after some simplifications:

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda ^{2}-\lambda \left( f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}} _{n}\right) +f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}\left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) =0 \end{aligned}$$

Eigenvalues can be found as the roots of this polynomial. We have:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta =\left( f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}\right) ^{2}-4f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}\left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) \end{aligned}$$

Note that \(\Delta\) can be rewritten as:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta= & {} \left( f_{p}s_{p}(1-m_{p})\right) ^{2}+\left( f_{n}s_{n}(1-m_{n})\right) ^{2}+2f_{p}s_{p}(1-m_{p})f_{n}s_{n}(1-m_{n}) \\&-4f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}\left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) \\= & {} \left( f_{p}s_{p}(1-m_{p})\right) ^{2}+\left( f_{n}s_{n}(1-m_{n})\right) ^{2}\\&-2f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}(1-m_{p}-m_{n})+2f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}m_{p}m_{n} \\= & {} \left( f_{p}s_{p}(1-m_{p})\right) ^{2}+\left( f_{n}s_{n}(1-m_{n})\right) ^{2}\\&-2f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}(1-m_{p}-m_{n}-m_{p}m_{n}) \end{aligned}$$

Hence the two eigenvalues are:

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _{1}= & {} \frac{\left( f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}} _{n}\right) +\root 2 \of {\left( f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}} _{n}\right) ^{2}-4f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}\left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) }}{2} \\ \lambda _{2}= & {} \frac{\left( f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}} _{n}\right) -\root 2 \of {\left( f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}} _{n}\right) ^{2}-4f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}\left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) }}{2} \end{aligned}$$

We have \(\lambda _{1}>\lambda _{2}\), so that the dominant eigenvalue is \(\lambda _{1}\).

We can then derive the long-run population structure by calculating the eigenvector \({\mathbf {w}}_{1}\) associated to the dominant eigenvalue \(\lambda _{1}\). The associated eigenvector is such that:

$$\begin{aligned}&\left( \begin{array}{cc} f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p} &{} f_{n}s_{n}m_{n} \\ f_{p}s_{p}m_{p} &{} f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n} \end{array} \right) \left( \begin{array}{c} N_{p} \\ N_{n} \end{array} \right) \\&\quad =\left( \frac{f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}+\root 2 \of { \begin{array}{l} \left( f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}\right) ^{2} \\ -4f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}\left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) \end{array} }}{2}\right) \left( \begin{array}{c} N_{p} \\ N_{n} \end{array} \right) \end{aligned}$$

Hence we have

$$\begin{aligned}&f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}N_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}m_{n}N_{n} \\&\quad =\frac{f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}} _{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}+\root 2 \of { \begin{array}{l} \left( f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}\right) ^{2} \\ -4f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}\left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) \end{array} }}{2}N_{p} \\&\quad f_{p}s_{p}m_{p}N_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}N_{n} \\&\quad =\frac{f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}} _{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}+\root 2 \of { \begin{array}{l} \left( f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}\right) ^{2} \\ -4f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}\left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) \end{array} }}{2}N_{n} \end{aligned}$$

Two equations and two unknowns. Normalizing to \(N_{p}+N_{n}=1\), the second equation can be rewritten as:

$$\begin{aligned}&f_{p}s_{p}m_{p}N_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}\left( 1-N_{p}\right) \\&\quad =\frac{ f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}+\root 2 \of { \begin{array}{l} \left( f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}\right) ^{2} \\ -4f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}\left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) \end{array} }}{2}(1-N_{p}) \end{aligned}$$

From which it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} N_{p}=\frac{f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}-f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}+\root 2 \of {\left( f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}\right) ^{2}-4f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}\left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) }}{ 2f_{p}s_{p}-(f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n})+\root 2 \of {\left( f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}\right) ^{2}-4f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}\left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) }} \end{aligned}$$

Hence the eigen vector associated to \(\lambda _{1}\) is

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathbf {w}}_{1}= & {} \left( \frac{N_{p}}{N_{n}}\right) \\= & {} \left( \frac{N_{p}}{1-N_{p} }\right) =\left( \begin{array}{c} \frac{f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}-f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}+\root 2 \of {\left( f_{p}s_{p} {\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}\right) ^{2}-4f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}\left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) }}{2f_{p}s_{p}-(f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}} _{n})+\root 2 \of {\left( f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}\right) ^{2}-4f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}\left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) }} \\ \frac{2f_{p}s_{p}\left( 1-{\bar{m}}_{p}\right) }{2f_{p}s_{p}-(f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}} _{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n})+\root 2 \of {\left( f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n} {\bar{m}}_{n}\right) ^{2}-4f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}\left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) }} \end{array} \right) \end{aligned}$$

From the Strong Ergodic Theorem, we have that

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\frac{{\mathbf {N}}_{t}}{\lambda _{1}^{t}}=c_{1} {\mathbf {w}}_{1} \end{aligned}$$

that is, the asymptotic population structure is given by the eigen vector \({\mathbf {w}}_{1}\), while the precise size of the different population groups can always be scaled as desired, since eigenvectors are always defined up to a multiplicative constant.

Hence the long-run headcount is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} {\rm HC}=\frac{N_{p}}{N_{p}+N_{n}}=\frac{f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}-f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}} _{n}+\root 2 \of { \begin{array}{l} \left( f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}\right) ^{2} \\ -4f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}\left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) \end{array} }}{2f_{p}s_{p}-f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}-f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}+\root 2 \of { \begin{array}{l} \left( f_{p}s_{p}{\bar{m}}_{p}+f_{n}s_{n}{\bar{m}}_{n}\right) ^{2} \\ -4f_{p}f_{n}s_{n}s_{p}\left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) \end{array} }} \end{aligned}$$

1.3 Proof of Proposition 3

Let us substitute for \(f_{n}s_{n}=\mu f_{p}s_{p}\) in the long-run poverty rate of Proposition 2. We obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} {\rm HC}=\frac{{\bar{m}}_{p}-\mu {\bar{m}}_{n}+\root 2 \of {\left( {\bar{m}}_{p}+\mu {\bar{m}} _{n}\right) ^{2}-4\mu \left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) }}{2-{\bar{m}}_{p}-\mu \bar{m }_{n}+\root 2 \of {\left( {\bar{m}}_{p}+\mu {\bar{m}}_{n}\right) ^{2}-4\mu \left( 1-m_{n}-m_{p}\right) }} \end{aligned}$$

Let us define \(\phi \equiv \root 2 \of {\left( {\bar{m}}_{p}\right) ^{2}+\left( \mu {\bar{m}}_{n}\right) ^{2}+2{\bar{m}}_{p}\mu {\bar{m}}_{n}-4\mu {\bar{m}} _{n}-4\mu {\bar{m}}_{p}+4\mu }\). Hence the headcount ratio is:

$$\begin{aligned} {\rm HC}=\frac{{\bar{m}}_{p}-\mu {\bar{m}}_{n}+\phi }{2-{\bar{m}}_{p}-\mu {\bar{m}} _{n}+\phi } \end{aligned}$$

The derivative of the headcount with respect to \(\mu\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial {\rm HC}}{\partial \mu }=\left( -{\bar{m}}_{n}+\phi ^{\prime }\right) 2\frac{(1-{\bar{m}}_{p})}{\left( 2-{\bar{m}}_{p}-\mu {\bar{m}}_{n}+\phi \right) ^{2}} \end{aligned}$$

Whose sign depends on the sign of \(-{\bar{m}}_{n}+\phi ^{\prime }.\)

Hence we have:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial {\rm HC}}{\partial \phi }\gtrless & {} 0\iff \phi ^{\prime }\gtrless {\bar{m}}_{n} \\\iff & {} \frac{1}{2}\frac{\left[ 2\left( \mu {\bar{m}}_{n}\right) {\bar{m}}_{n}+2 {\bar{m}}_{p}{\bar{m}}_{n}-4{\bar{m}}_{n}-4{\bar{m}}_{p}+4\right] }{\left[ \left( {\bar{m}}_{p}\right) ^{2}+\left( \mu {\bar{m}}_{n}\right) ^{2}+2{\bar{m}}_{p}\mu {\bar{m}}_{n}-4\mu {\bar{m}}_{n}-4\mu {\bar{m}}_{p}+4\mu \right] ^{\frac{1}{2}}} \gtrless {\bar{m}}_{n} \\\iff & {} \frac{\left[ 2\left( \mu {\bar{m}}_{n}\right) {\bar{m}}_{n}+2{\bar{m}}_{p} {\bar{m}}_{n}-4{\bar{m}}_{n}-4{\bar{m}}_{p}+4\right] }{2\phi }\gtrless {\bar{m}}_{n} \\\iff & {} \frac{{\bar{m}}_{n}\left( \mu {\bar{m}}_{n}+{\bar{m}}_{p}\right) -2{\bar{m}} _{n}-2{\bar{m}}_{p}+2}{\phi }\gtrless {\bar{m}}_{n} \end{aligned}$$

Since \({\rm HC}=\frac{{\bar{m}}_{p}-\mu {\bar{m}}_{n}+\phi }{2-{\bar{m}}_{p}-\mu {\bar{m}} _{n}+\phi }\rightarrow \frac{{\rm HC}\left( 2-{\bar{m}}_{p}-\mu {\bar{m}}_{n}\right) - {\bar{m}}_{p}+\mu {\bar{m}}_{n}}{(1-{\rm HC})}=\phi .\)

Hence the condition can be written as:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\bar{m}}_{n}\left( \mu {\bar{m}}_{n}+{\bar{m}}_{p}\right) -2{\bar{m}}_{n}-2 {\bar{m}}_{p}+2}{\frac{{\rm HC}\left( 2-{\bar{m}}_{p}-\mu {\bar{m}}_{n}\right) -{\bar{m}} _{p}+\mu {\bar{m}}_{n}}{(1-{\rm HC})}}\gtrless & {} {\bar{m}}_{n} \\ (1-{\rm HC})\left[ {\bar{m}}_{n}\left( \mu {\bar{m}}_{n}+{\bar{m}}_{p}\right) -2{\bar{m}} _{n}-2{\bar{m}}_{p}+2\right]\gtrless & {} {\bar{m}}_{n}\left[ 2{\rm HC}-{\rm HC}\left( {\bar{m}} _{p}\right. \right. \\&\left. \left. +\mu {\bar{m}}_{n}\right) -{\bar{m}}_{p}+\mu {\bar{m}}_{n}\right] \\ \left[ {\bar{m}}_{n}\left( \mu {\bar{m}}_{n}+{\bar{m}}_{p}\right) -2{\bar{m}}_{n}-2 {\bar{m}}_{p}+2\right] -{\rm HC}\left[ -2{\bar{m}}_{p}+2\right]\gtrless & {} {\bar{m}}_{n} \left[ -{\bar{m}}_{p}+\mu {\bar{m}}_{n}\right] \\ {\bar{m}}_{n}{\bar{m}}_{p}-{\bar{m}}_{n}-{\bar{m}}_{p}+1-{\rm HC}\left[ -{\bar{m}}_{p}+1 \right]\gtrless & {} 0 \\ {\bar{m}}_{n}({\bar{m}}_{p}-1)+(1-{\bar{m}}_{p})(1-{\rm HC})\gtrless & {} 0 \\ 1-{\rm HC}\gtrless & {} {\bar{m}}_{n} \end{aligned}$$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lefebvre, M., Pestieau, P. & Ponthiere, G. Counting the missing poor in pre-industrial societies. Cliometrica 17, 155–183 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-022-00243-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-022-00243-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation