Skip to main content
Log in

Advertising and tax avoidance

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine the link between firms’ advertising and their tax avoidance. By generating customer awareness, advertising helps shape firm image and reputation among customers. Such benefits of advertising would diminish if the firm is viewed as a greedy tax dodger. Greater customer awareness generated by higher advertising spending also increases the likelihood that customers would find out tax-aggressive behaviors of the firm. Thus, firms that spend more on advertising may want to be less tax-aggressive. Consistent with this argument, we find that firms with a greater extent of advertising spending have fewer tax-sheltering activities, smaller book-tax differences, and higher cash-effective tax rates. The negative effect of advertising on tax avoidance is stronger for firms that are less known, more opaque, or that have lower institutional holdings. We control for other factors affecting tax avoidance, including corporate governance and social responsibility ratings. We also use the instrumental variable method, propensity score matching, and change regressions to address endogeneity concerns. Our results remain statistically and economically significant.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Servaes and Tamayo (2013) argue that higher advertising spending increases the likelihood that customers find out and reward the firm for its socially responsible activities.

  2. See https://money.cnn.com/2011/11/03/news/economy/corporate_taxes/index.htm.

  3. See www.theguardian.com/business/2013/jun/10/consumer-likely-boycott-tax-avoidance.

  4. See www.nytimes.com/2012/12/07/business/global/07iht-uktax07.html.

  5. Poor corporate ethics can affect the reputation of firm insiders. Fich and Shivdasani (2007) document a negative impact to firms’ outside directors, following financial fraud allegations against the firms.

  6. Stiglitz (2000) argues that the lack of corporate informational transparency is an important factor that can lead to misalignments of interest among stakeholders of the firm, which in turn can result in reduced outside investments.

  7. Advertising expense (item 45) is not available for banks or utility firms.

  8. We also use the unbalanced panel sample, and the inference from our main regression is unchanged.

  9. A higher rank is associated with a higher level of opacity—a lower trading volume, a greater bid-ask spread, fewer analyst coverages, or higher analyst forecast errors.

  10. We also use the ratio of advertising to sales, and to assets, as additional robustness checks, and the results are similar.

  11. To see the importance of the amount of advertising spending, take as an example that in 2012, General Motors (GM) spent $5.37 billion while CenturyLink (CTL) spent $189 million on advertising. In term of advertising’s reach to consumers, GM’s $5.37 billion would obviously go much further than CTL’s $189 million, irrespective of the relative significance of each’s advertising spending.

  12. We carry out sensitivity analysis by excluding the lag of book-tax differences from our baseline regressions. Our inferences on the two measures of advertising remain unchanged.

  13. We use the lag of advertising expenditure as additional robustness check, and our results remain consistent.

  14. For additional robustness check, we create the high advertising dummy HADVDUMi,t, which is equal to one if advertising expenditure is above the median level. The results are consistent with our baseline regressions.

  15. The decrease in sheltering probability is computed as the estimated marginal effect of Log(ADV)i,t (ADVGPi,t) on tax-sheltering probability, i.e., the expected decrease in sheltering probability as a function of variable Log(ADV)i,t (ADVGPi,t), holding all other variables in Eq. (1) at the sample mean.

  16. Specifically, we exclude firms that fall into the categories of GOVDOM, GOVFRN, GOVLOC, and GOVSTATE in the Compustat Customer Segment dataset.

  17. When Log(ADV)i,t is the dependent variable in the first-stage regression, the Cragg-Donald F-statistics on CETRi,t, KIMBTDi,t, DDKIMBTDi,t, and DTAXi,t are 27.05, 44.29, 44.45, and 24.39, respectively. Stock and Yogo (2005) suggest that for one endogenous regressor (n = 1) and one instrumental variable (K = 1), the critical value is 16.38 for weak instrument based on the maximum size bias at the 5% significance level. See Table 5.2 in Stock and Yogo (2005) for details.

  18. Following Fama and French (2001), we estimate the Logit regressions each year and report the average coefficients and pseudo R-square. T-value is estimated based on the time-series standard deviations of the regression coefficients.

  19. We follow the Newey–West adjustment for standard errors using three lags.

  20. Relatedly, Lim (2012) shows the marginal substitution effect of tax avoidance on the use of debt and Gao et al. (2016) look into the relationship between tax avoidance and innovation.

References

  • Anderson RC, Duru A, Reeb DM (2009) Founders, heirs, and corporate opacity in the United States. J Financ Econ 92:205–222

    Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong CS, Blouin JL, Larcker DF (2012) The incentives for tax planning. J Account Econ 53:391–411

    Google Scholar 

  • Austin CR, Wilson R (2016) An examination of reputational costs and tax avoidance: evidence from firms with valuable consumer brands. J Am Tax Assoc 39:67–93

    Google Scholar 

  • Balakrishnan K, Blouin JL, Guay WR (2018) Tax aggressiveness and corporate transparency. Account Rev. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-52130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bebchuk L, Cohen A, Ferrell A (2008) What matters in corporate governance? Rev Financ Stud 22:783–827

    Google Scholar 

  • Borghesi R, Houston JF, Naranjo A (2014) Corporate socially responsible investments: CEO altruism, reputation, and shareholder interests. J Corp Finance 26:164–181

    Google Scholar 

  • Bushman R, Chen Q, Engel E, Smith A (2004) Financial accounting information, organizational complexity and corporate governance systems. J Account Econ 37:167–201

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen SP, Chen X, Cheng Q, Shevlin T (2010) Are family firms more tax aggressive than non-family firms? J Financ Econ 95:41–61

    Google Scholar 

  • Comanor WS, Wilson TA (1974) Advertising and market power. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Cordis A, Kirby C (2018) Income shifting as an aspect of tax avoidance: evidence from U.S. multinational corporations. Rev Pac Basin Financ Mark Policies 21:1–53

    Google Scholar 

  • Cormwell TB, Roy DP, Steinard EA II (2001) Exploring managers’ perceptions of the impact of sponsorship on brand equity. J Advert 30:2–41

    Google Scholar 

  • Crabtree AD, Kubick TR (2014) Corporate tax avoidance and the timeliness of annual earnings announcements. Rev Quant Finance Account 42:51–67

    Google Scholar 

  • Desai MA, Dharmapala D (2006) Corporate tax avoidance and high-power incentives. J Financ Econ 79:145–179

    Google Scholar 

  • Desai MA, Dharmapala D (2009a) Corporate tax avoidance and firm value. Rev Econ Stat 91:537–546

    Google Scholar 

  • Desai MA, Dharmapala D (2009b) Earnings management, corporate tax shelters, and book-tax alignment. Natl Tax J 62:169–186

    Google Scholar 

  • Desai MA, Dyck A, Zingales L (2007) Theft and taxes. J Financ Econ 84:591–623

    Google Scholar 

  • Dyreng SD, Hanlon M, Maydew EL (2008) Long-run corporate tax avoidance. Account Rev 83:61–82

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, French KR (2001) Disappearing dividends: changing firm characteristics or lower propensity to pay? J Financ Econ 60:3–43

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, MacBeth JD (1973) Risk, return, and equilibrium: empirical tests. J Polit Econ 81:607–636

    Google Scholar 

  • Fich EM, Shivdasani A (2007) Financial fraud, director reputation, and shareholder wealth. J Financ Econ 86:306–336

    Google Scholar 

  • Fombrun CJ, Shanley M (1990) What’s in a name? Reputation building and corporate strategy. Acad Manag J 33:233–258

    Google Scholar 

  • Fombrun CJ, Gardberg NA, Sever JM (2000) The reputation quotient: a multi-stakeholder measure of corporate reputation. J Brand Manag 7:241–255

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank MM, Lynch LJ, Rego SO (2009) Tax reporting aggressiveness and its relation to aggressive financial reporting. Account Rev 84:467–496

    Google Scholar 

  • Frieder L, Subrahmanyam A (2005) Brand perceptions and market for common stocks. J Financ Quant Anal 40:57–86

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallemore J, Maydew EL, Thornock JR (2014) The reputational costs of tax avoidance. Contemp Account Res 31:1103–1133

    Google Scholar 

  • Gao L, Yang LL, Zhang JH (2016) Corporate patents, R&D success, and tax avoidance. Rev Quant Finance Account 47:1063–1096

    Google Scholar 

  • Graham JR, Hanlon M, Shevlin T, Shroff N (2014) Incentives for tax planning and avoidance: evidence from the field. Account Rev 89:991–1023

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman G, Shapiro C (1984) Informative advertising with differentiated products. Rev Econ Stud 51:63–81

    Google Scholar 

  • Grullon G, Kanatas G, Weston JP (2004) Advertising, breadth of ownership, and liquidity. Rev Financ Stud 17:439–461

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanlon M, Hertzman S (2010) A review of tax research. J Account Econ 50:127–178

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen V, Lopez TJ, Reitenga A (2017) The executive compensation implications of the tax component of earnings. Rev Quant Finance Account 48:557–595

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoi CK, Wu Q, Zhang H (2013) Is corporate social responsibility (CSR) associated with tax avoidance? Evidence from irresponsible CSR activities. Account Rev 88:2025–2059

    Google Scholar 

  • Hribar P, Collins DW (2002) Errors in estimating accruals: implications for empirical research. J Account Res 40:105–134

    Google Scholar 

  • Hyytinen A, Pajarinen M (2008) Opacity of young businesses: evidence from rating disagreements. J Bank Finance 32:1234–1241

    Google Scholar 

  • Jorgensen PEF, Isaksson M (2008) Building credibility in international banking and financial markets: a study of how corporate reputations are managed through image advertising. Corp Commun Int J 13:365–379

    Google Scholar 

  • Keller KL (2001) Building customer-based brand equity: a blueprint for creating strong brand. Mark Sci Inst 107:3–38

    Google Scholar 

  • Khurana IK, Moser WJ (2013) Institutional shareholders’ investment horizons and tax avoidance. J Am Tax Assoc 35:111–134

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim CF, Zhang LD (2016) Corporate political connections and tax aggressiveness. Contemp Account Res 33:78–114

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim JB, Li YH, Zhang LD (2011) Corporate tax avoidance and stock price crash risk: firm-level analysis. J Financ Econ 100:639–662

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein B, Leffler K (1981) The role of market forces in assuring contractual performance. J Polit Econ 89:615–641

    Google Scholar 

  • Lanis R, Richardson G (2012) Corporate social responsibility and tax aggressiveness: an empirical analysis. J Account Public Policy 31:86–108

    Google Scholar 

  • Lim Y (2012) Tax avoidance and underleverage puzzle: Korean evidence. Rev Quant Finance Account 39:333–360

    Google Scholar 

  • Lo A, Mamaysky H, Wang J (2004) Asset prices and trading volume under fixed transaction costs. J Polit Econ 112:1054–1090

    Google Scholar 

  • Manzon G, Plesko G (2002) The relation between financial and tax reporting measures. Tax Law Rev 55:175–214

    Google Scholar 

  • Mcleod DM, Kunita M (1994) A comparative analysis of the use of corporate advertising in the United States and Japan. Int J Advert 13:137–151

    Google Scholar 

  • Mills LF (1998) Book-tax differences and Internal Revenue Service adjustment. J Account Res 36:343–356

    Google Scholar 

  • Mizruchi MS, Schwartz M (1992) Intercorporate relations: the structural analysis of business. Cambridge University Press, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson P (1974) Advertising as information. J Polit Econ 82:729–754

    Google Scholar 

  • Pashupati L, Arpan L, Nikolaev A (2002) Corporate advertising as inoculation against negative news: an experimental investigation of efficacy and presentation order effects. J Curr Issues Res Advert 24:1–15

    Google Scholar 

  • Rego SO, Wilson R (2012) Equity risk incentives and corporate tax aggressiveness. J Account Res 504:775–810

    Google Scholar 

  • Rumelt RP (1987) Theory, strategy, and entrepreneurship. In: Teece DJ (ed) The competitive challenge: strategies for industrial innovation and renewal. Ballinger Publishing, Cambridge, MA, pp 137–158

    Google Scholar 

  • Scholes M, Wolfson M, Erickson M, Maydew E, Shevlin T (2005) Taxes and business strategy: a planning approach, 3rd edn. Prentice-Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Servaes H, Tamayo A (2013) The impact of corporate social responsibility on firm value: the role of customer awareness. Manag Sci 59:1045–1061

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith KT, Smith LM, Dunbar S (2014) Using corporate advertising to improve public perception of energy companies. J Strateg Mark 22:347–356

    Google Scholar 

  • Staiger D, Stock JH (1997) Instrumental variables regression with weak instruments. Econometrica 65:557–586

    Google Scholar 

  • Stephen AG (1999) Advancing and enhancing corporate reputation. Corp Commun Int J 4:177–181

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz J (2000) The contributions of the economics of information to twentieth century economics. Q J Econ 115:1441–1478

    Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH, Yogo M (2005) Testing for weak instruments in linear IV regression. In: Andrews DWK, Stocks JH (eds) Identification and inference for econometric models: essays in honor of Thomas Rothenberg. Cambridge University Press, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson R (2009) An examination of corporate tax shelter participants. Account Rev 84:969–999

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Dan Bradley, Miran Hossain, Chris Pantzalis, Matt Pierson, Ninon Sutton, session participants at the 2016 Florida Finance Conference and a University of South Florida seminar, two anonymous reviewers and the editor for helpful comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jianping Qi.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix 1

Appendix 1

Variable definitions

Variable

Definition

 

Measures of tax aggressiveness and advertising

SHELTERi,t

Wilson’s (2009) sheltering probability is computed using the following regression model (Table 5 Column 3):

\(\begin{aligned} {\text{SHELTER}}\_{\text{PROB}}_{\text{it}} & = - 4.86 + 5.20 \times {\text{BTD}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}} + 4.08 \times {\text{DA}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}} - 0.41 \times {\text{LEV}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}} \\ & \quad + 0.76 \times {\text{AT}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}} + 3.51 \times {\text{ROA}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}} + 1.72 \times {\text{FI}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}} + 2.43 \times {\text{RD}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}} \\ \end{aligned}\)

The above \({\text{SHELTER}}\_{\text{PROB}}_{\text{it}}\) is the sheltering probability from firm i in year t. \({\text{BTD}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}}\) is the book-tax difference \({\text{KIMBTD}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}}\) used in Kim et al. (2011). \({\text{DA}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}}\) is discretionary accruals from the performance-adjusted modified cross-sectional Jones Model. \({\text{LEV}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}}\) is the long-term debt scaled by lagged asset (#9/#6). \({\text{AT}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}}\) is the Log of total asset (#6). \({\text{ROA}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}}\) is the return on assets measured as operating income (#170 minus #192) scaled by lagged assets (#6). \({\text{FI}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}}\) (#273) is a dummy variable, which equals one for a firm-year that reports foreign income and zero otherwise. \({\text{RD}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}}\) is research and development expenses scaled by lagged total assets (#46/#6). Following Rego and Wilson (2012), we rank \({\text{SHELTER}}\_{\text{PROB}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}}\) each year and create a dummy variable to capture firms that have a high sheltering probability. In particular, SHELTERi,t is an indicator variable that equals one if the firm’s estimated sheltering probability is in the top quartile in that year, and zero otherwise

CETRi,t

Defined as Cash Taxes Paid/Pretax Income (#317 divided by #170). CETRi,t is set to missing when the denominator is zero or negative. It is truncated to the range of [0, 1]

KIMBTDi,t

Defined as book income (#170) minus taxable income over lagged assets (#6). Taxable income is computed as the sum of current federal tax expense (#63) and current foreign tax expense (#64) divided by the statutory tax rate, and then subtracted the change in net operating loss carryforwards (#52). If current deferral tax expense is missing, total current tax expense is calculated by subtracting deferred taxes (#50), state income taxes (#173), and other income tax (#211) from total income taxes (#16) in year t

DDKIMBTDi,t

Desai and Dharmapala’s (2006) residual book-tax difference, which equals the residual of the firm fixed effect regression: \({\text{KIMBTD}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}} =\upbeta_{1} {\text{TACC}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}} +\upmu_{\text{i}} +\upvarepsilon_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}}\), where \({\text{TACC}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}}\) is total accruals measured using the cash flow method of Hribar and Collins (2002). Both variables are scaled by lagged total assets (#6) and are winsorized at the 1% and 99% levels

DTAXi,t

Frank et al.’s (2009) discretionary permanent book-tax difference for firm i in year t, \({\text{DTAX}}_{{{\text{i}},{\text{t}}}}\), is the \(\upvarepsilon_{\text{it}}\) from the following regression estimated by 2-digit SIC code and fiscal year:

\({\text{PERMDIFF}}_{\text{it}} =\upbeta_{0} +\upbeta_{1} {\text{INTANG}}_{\text{it}} +\upbeta_{2} {\text{UNCON}}_{\text{it}} +\upbeta_{3} {\text{MI}}_{\text{it}} +\upbeta_{4} {\text{CSTS}}_{\text{it}} +\upbeta_{5} \Delta {\text{NOL}}_{\text{it}} +\upbeta_{6} {\text{LAGPERM}}_{\text{it}} +\upvarepsilon_{\text{it}}\)

where

\({\text{PERMDIFF}}_{\text{it}} = {\text{BI}}_{\text{it}} - \left[ {({\text{CFTE}}_{\text{it}} + {\text{CFOR}}_{\text{it}} )/{\text{STR}}_{\text{it}} } \right) - ({\text{DTE}}_{\text{it}} /{\text{STR}}_{\text{it}} )\)

\({\text{BI}}_{\text{it}}\) = pre-tax book income (#170) for firm i in year t

\({\text{CFTE}}_{\text{it}}\) = current federal tax expense (#63) for firm i in year t

\({\text{CFOR}}_{\text{it}}\) = current foreign tax expense (#64) for firm i in year t

\({\text{STR}}_{\text{it}}\) = statutory tax rate in year t

\({\text{DTE}}_{\text{it}}\) = deferred tax expense (#50) for firm i in year t

\({\text{INTANG}}_{\text{it}}\) = good will and other intangibles (#33) for firm i in year t

\({\text{UNCON}}_{\text{it}}\) = income (loss) reported under the equity method (#55) for firm i in year t

\({\text{MI}}_{\text{it}}\) = income (loss) attributable to minority interest (#49) for firm i in year t

\({\text{CSTE}}_{\text{it}}\) = current state income tax expense (#173) for firm i in year t

\(\Delta {\text{NOL}}_{\text{it}}\) = change in net operating expense (#52) for firm i in year t

\({\text{LAGPERM}}_{\text{it}}\) = 1-year lagged PERMDIFF firm i in year t.

Following Frank et al. (2009), we handle the missing value problems as follows: if \({\text{MI}}_{\text{it}}\),\({\text{CFOR}}_{\text{it}}\),\({\text{UNCON}}_{\text{it}}\), or \({\text{CSTE}}_{\text{it}}\) is missing, it is set to zero. If \({\text{CFTE}}_{\text{it}}\) (#63) is missing, then \({\text{CFTE}}_{\text{it}}\) is computed as total tax expense (#16) less current foreign tax expense (\(\# 64)\), less current state tax expense (#173), and less deferred tax expense (#50). If \({\text{INTANG}}_{\text{it}}\) (#33) is missing, then it is set to zero. If \({\text{INTANG}}_{\text{it}}\) (#33) = “C”, then it equals that for good will (#204)

Log(ADV)i,t

Natural logarithm of one plus advertising expenditure (#45) times 1,000,000

ADVGPi,t

Ratio of advertising expenditure (#45) to gross profits (#12-#41)

HADVDUMi,t

Dummy variable that equals one if advertising expenditure is above the median, and zero otherwise

 

Firm specific variables

High_Neg_CSRi,t

Following Hoi et al. (2013), we construct a CSR (corporate social responsibility) weakness index based on seven categories: corporate governance, employee relations, environment, community, diversity, human rights, and product quality and safety. High_Neg_CSRi,t is an indicator variable on negative CSR activities, which equals one when firm i has four or more irresponsible CSR activities in year t, and zero otherwise

OPACITYi,t

Following Anderson et al. (2009), we compute opacity by aggregating the decile ranks from four variables: bid-ask spread, trading volume, analyst coverage, and analyst forecast errors, and then dividing the sum by 40. Trading volume is the nature logarithm of average daily trading volume during a fiscal year. Bid-ask spread is ask-price minus bid-price over the average of bid and ask prices, computed by averaging all trades for each firm from the third Wednesday of each month and then calculated a yearly average based on these 12 observations. Analyst coverage is the natural logarithm of the number of analysts following each firm, and analyst forecast error is the square of difference between the mean analysts’ earnings forecast and actual firms’ earnings scaled by the firm’s stock price

SP1500i,t

Dummy variable that equals one if a firm is listed in the S&P 1500 firms over a firm year

INST.OWNi,t

Percentage of shares owned by institutional investors scaled by common shares outstanding

ROAi,t

Return on assets measured as operating income (#170 minus #192) scaled by lagged assets (#6)

LEVi,t

Leverage ratio measured as long-term debt (#9) scaled by lagged asset (#6)

ΔNOIi,t

Change in loss carry forward (#52) scaled by lagged asset (#6)

NOIi,t

Dummy variable that equals one if loss carry forward (#52) is positive as of the beginning of the year

FIi,t

Foreign income (#273) for firm i, year t, scaled by lagged assets (#6)

PPEi,t

Property, plant, and equipment (#8) scaled by lagged assets (#6)

INTANGi,t

Intangible assets (#33) scaled by lagged assets (#6)

EQINCi,t

Equity income in earnings (#55) scaled by lagged assets (#6)

SIZEi,t

Natural logarithm of firm i’s total assets (#6)

MTBi,t−1

Market-to-book ratio for firm i, at the beginning of year t, measured as market value of equity [(#199) × (#25)], scaled by book value of equity (#60)

RDi,t

Research and development ratio measured as research and development expenses (#46) scaled by lagged total assets (#6). Missing values are set to zero

CASHi,t

Cash and cash equivalents (#1) scaled by lag of total assets (#6) net of cash

LAGEi,t

Natural logarithms of firm age in Compustat

DIVi,t

Dummy variable that equals one if a firm pays dividends (#201) at year t, and zero otherwise

EMPi,t

Number of employees in the firm (#29) in thousands at year t

High_Eindexi,t

Following Bebchuk et al. (2008), we construct an entrenchment index, Eindex, based on six categories: staggered board, limitation on amending bylaws, limitation on amending the charter, supermajority to approve a merger, golden parachute, and poison pill. High_Eindexi,t is an indicator variable on strong entrenchment or weak governance, which equals one if firm i has at least three potential red flags on governance issues at year t, and zero otherwise

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mansi, S., Qi, J. & Shi, H. Advertising and tax avoidance. Rev Quant Finan Acc 54, 479–516 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-019-00796-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-019-00796-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation