Skip to main content
Log in

The executive compensation implications of the tax component of earnings

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We extend prior research by examining the weight applied to earnings generated by changes in ETRs (i.e., the tax component of earnings) in determining CEO and CFO compensation. We examine both bonus and total compensation and find that the predicted relationships between compensation and the tax component of earnings are largely limited to bonus compensation. This is not surprising since bonus compensation represents an unambiguous link between contemporaneous performance and compensation, while equity compensation is in part determined by agency considerations. Our evidence suggests that both CEOs and CFOs are compensated for the tax component of earnings. We find that CEOs are rewarded equally for the tax component of earnings relative to other components of earnings, while CFOs are rewarded more for the tax component of earnings relative to other components of earnings. Additionally, the weight applied to the tax component of earnings when determining CFO bonus compensation is greater when; (1) the tax component of earnings does not appear to be related to earnings management; (2) ETRs decrease rather than increase, (3) the firm pays bonus based on after-tax earnings rather than pre-tax earnings, and (4) the firm is tax aggressive rather than non-tax aggressive. The variations in the weighting of the tax component of earnings for CFO bonus compensation noted above in combination with evidence that CEO bonus compensation is indifferent to ETR-related earnings versus other components of earnings, suggests that the tax component of earnings is a contractual component of CFO bonus compensation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Specifically, Hollingsworth (2002) reports that 86 percent of the corporate tax department executives who responded to her 2001 survey cite tax savings as an important metric in their performance evaluation and 56 percent specifically note the use of ETRs as a performance benchmark. More importantly, Hollingsworth reports that 60 percent of these executives state that these measures are used in determining their compensation.

  2. The tax component of earnings is measured as the pretax return on assets times the change in the effective tax rate.

  3. In addition to the change in ETR measure mentioned above, we also estimate two additional changes in ETR measures to calculate TAX_COMP. The first is based on the method of Abarbanell and Bushee (1997). Their measure calculates the change in ETR as the prior three-year average ETR less the current year ETR. The second is a change in cash ETR measure consistent with Dyreng et al. (2008). Specifically, we measure the change in the cash ETR as the prior 5-year cash ETR less the current cash ETR. Our results (not reported) are robust to the calculations of TAX_COMP using the Abarbanell and Bushee (1997) method. We discuss the empirical results using the cash ETR in the sensitivity analysis section.

  4. In additional testing (not reported), we replicate the work of Schmidt (2006) with our sample.

  5. We use two additional procedures to test the influence of earnings management. First, Schmidt (2006) suggests the initial tax component of earnings (i.e., based on the first quarter ETR) is more persistent for future earnings than is the revised tax component of earnings (i.e., based on the end of year ETR). In supplemental testing (not tabulated), we re-estimate Eq. (2) using first quarter ETR as the measure of the expected ETR. Our conclusions are robust to this alternative specification. Second, Dhaliwal et al. (2004) report that firms’ lower their fourth-quarter ETRs when they would otherwise miss their consensus earnings forecast absent tax expense manipulation. Thus, rather than using prior year’s ROA as the benchmark, we re-estimate our tests based on whether the 4th quarter tax component of earnings is greater than the analysts’ earnings forecast error. Our conclusions are robust to this alternative specification. We do not use this as our primary test as we lose over half of our sample observations when we include analysts’ forecasts in our data set.

  6. Gaertner (2014) validates this model by choosing a random sample of fifty firms. The model has an accuracy rate of 94 % in predicting before or after-tax compensation of the executive.

  7. We use the CFOANN and job title fields in ExecuComp to identify CFOs. Any executive not identified in the CFOANN field that has a job title including the terms CFO or “chief financial” is coded as a CFO.

  8. The exceptions are ∆ADJ_ROA*PERS which is insignificant for CEO total compensation, PSI which is insignificant for CFO bonus compensation and CEO total compensation, and NSI which is insignificant for CFO total compensation.

  9. We employ two separate measures of discretionary accruals (PADCA and REDCA) that control for firm performance based on the work of Ashbaugh et al. (2003). The first measure of discretionary accruals, PADCA, controls for firm performance through a portfolio technique. The second measure of discretionary accruals, REDCA, adjusts for firm performance by including lagged return on assets in the regression model used to estimate non-discretionary accruals. The specific procedures for estimating both measures are discussed in Ashbaugh et al. (2003, 621–622).

  10. The only exception is DTAX in the bonus compensation model where we find HTAX_COMP is significantly greater than LTAX_COMP (two-tailed p value <0.10).

  11. If minority interest (#49), current foreign tax expense (#64), income from unconsolidated entities (#55), or current state tax expense (#173) is missing on Compustat, then we set MI, CFOR, UNCON, or CSTE, respectively, to zero. If current federal tax expense (#63) is missing on Compustat, then we set the value of CFTE to: total tax expense (#16) less current foreign tax expense (#64) less current state tax expense (#173) less deferred tax expense (#50). If goodwill and other intangibles (#33) is missing on Compustat, then we set the value for INTANG to 0. If #33 = C, then we set the value of INTANG to that for goodwill (#204).

References

  • Abarbanell J, Bushee B (1997) Fundamental analysis, future earnings, and stock prices. J Account Res 35(1):1–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adut D, Cready W, Lopez T (2003) Restructuring charges and CEO cash compensation: a reexamination. Account Rev 78(1):169–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aggarwal RK, Samwick A (2003) Performance incentives within firms: the effect of managerial responsibility. J Finance 58:1613–1649

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antle R, Demski J (1988) The controllability principle in responsibility accounting. Account Rev 63(4):700–718

    Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong C, Blouin J, Larcker D (2012) The incentives for tax planning. J Account Econ 53(2):391–411

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashbaugh H, LaFond R, Mayhew B (2003) Do nonaudit services compromise auditor independence? Further evidence. Account Rev 78(3):611–639

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atwood TJ, Omer T, Shelley M (1998) Before versus after-tax earnings as performance measures in compensation contracts. Manag Finance 11:30–44

    Google Scholar 

  • Baber W, Kang S, Kumar K (1998) Accounting earnings and executive compensation: the role of earnings persistence. J Account Econ 25(2):169–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauman M, Shaw K (2005) Interim income tax data and earnings prediction. J Am Tax Assoc 27(2):57–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown J, Drake K, Martin M (2011) Are firms myopic? The case of contracting on performance and uncertainty. Working paper. Arizona State University

  • Bryant-Kutcher L, Guenther D, Jones D (2009) Earnings persistence and the value of change in firms’ effective tax rates. Working paper Colorado State University

  • Bushman R, Indjejikian R, Smith R (1995) Aggregate performance measures in business unit manager compensation: the role of intrafirm interdependencies. J Account Res 33:101–128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cao J, Laksmana I (2010) The effect of capital market pressures on the association between R&D spending and CEO option compensation. Rev Quant Finance Account 34(2):273–300

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carnes G, Guffey D (2000) The influence of international status and operating segments on firms’ choice of bonus plans. J Int Account Audit Tax 9(1):43–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carter ME, Lynch LJ, Zechman SL (2009) Changes in bonus contracts in the post-Sarbanes–Oxley era. Rev Account Stud 14(4):480–506

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheng S (2004) R&D expenditures and CEO compensation. Account Rev 79(April):305–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook K, Huston GR, Omer T (2008) Earnings management through effective tax rates: the effects of tax-planning investment and the Sarbanes–Oxley act of 2002. Contemp Account Res 25(2):447–471

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Core J, Guay W (1999) The use of equity grants to manage optimal equity incentive levels. J Account Econ 28:151–184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Core J, Holthausen R, Larcker D (1999) Corporate governance, chief executive officer compensation, and firm performance. J Finance Econ 51(March):371–406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dechow P, Huson M, Sloan R (1994) The effect of restructuring charges on executives’ cash compensation. Account Rev 69(1):138–156

    Google Scholar 

  • Dechow P, Myers L, Shakespeare C (2010) Fair value accounting and gains from asset securitizations: a convenient earnings management tool with compensation side-benefits. J Account Econ 49(1–2):2–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desai M, Dharmapala D (2006) Corporate tax avoidance and high-powered incentives. J Finance Econ 88:1–25

    Google Scholar 

  • Dhaliwal D, Gleason C, Mills L (2004) Last chance earnings management: using the tax expense to achieve earnings targets. Contemp Account Res 21(2):431–458

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Douglas R, Ellingsworth P, McAndrews J (1996) What management expects: evaluation of the tax department and its executives. Tax Exec 48:29–32

    Google Scholar 

  • Duru A, Iyengar R, Thevaranjan A (2002) The shielding of CEO compensation from the effects of strategic expenditures. Contemp Account Res 19(2):175–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dyreng S, Hanlon M, Maydew E (2008) Long-run corporate tax avoidance. Account Rev 83(1):61–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dyreng S, Hanlon M, Maydew E (2010) The effects of executives on corporate tax avoidance. Account Rev 85(4):1163–1189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank MM, Lynch LL, Rego SO (2009) Tax reporting aggressiveness and its relation to aggressive financial reporting. Account Rev 84(2):467–496

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman T (2010) What should a CFO know about tax. Finance Exec 26:52–55

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaertner F (2014) CEO: after-tax compensation incentives and corporate tax avoidance. Contemp Account Res 31(4):1077–1102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaver J, Gaver K (1998) The relation between nonrecurring accounting transactions and CEO cash compensation. Account Rev 73:235–254

    Google Scholar 

  • Gleason D, Mills L (2008) Evidence of differing market responses to beating analysts’ targets through tax expense decreases. Rev Account Stud 13:295–318

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gow I, Ormazabal G, Taylor D (2010) Correcting for cross-sectional and time-series dependence in accounting research. Account Rev 85(2):483–512

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham J, Tucker A (2006) Tax shelters and corporate debt policy. J Finance Econ 81(September):563–594

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gul F, Chen C, Tsui J (2003) Discretionary accounting accruals, managers’ incentives, and audit fees. Contemp Account Res 20(3):441–464

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanlon M, Heitzman S (2011) A review of tax research. J Account Econ 50:127–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanlon M, Mills L, Slemrod J (2005) An empirical examination of corporate tax noncompliance. In: Auerbach A, Hines J, Slemrod J (eds) Taxing corporate income in the twenty-first century. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Healy R (1985) The effect if bonus schemes on accounting decisions. J Account Econ 7(1–3):85–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Healy P, Kang S, Palepu K (1987) The effect of accounting procedure changes on CEOs’ cash salary and bonus compensation. J Account Econ 9(April):7–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hollingsworth T (2002) Manufacturers alliance/MAPI survey of corporate tax departments, 4th edn. Manufacturers Alliance/MAPI, Arlington, VA

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen M, Murphy K (1990) Performance pay and top management incentives. J Polit Econ 98(2):225–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jiménez-Angueira C, Stuart N (2015) Relative performance evaluation, pay-for-luck, and double-dipping in CEO compensation. Rev Quant Finance Account 44(4):701–732

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keating AS (1997) Determinants of divisional performance evaluation practices. J Account Econ 24(3):243–273

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lambert R, Larcker D (1987) An analysis of the use of accounting and market measures of performance in executive compensation. J Account Res 25(Supplement):85–129

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lev B, Thiagarajan SR (1993) Fundamental information analysis. J Account Res 31(2):190–215

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lim Y (2012) Tax avoidance and underleverage puzzle: Korean evidence. Rev Quant Finance Account 39(3):333–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matolcsy Z (2000) Executive cash compensation and corporate performance during different economic cycles. Contemp Account Res 17(4):671–692

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy K (1985) Corporate performance and managerial remuneration: an empirical analysis. J Account Econ 7(April):11–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newman H (1989) Selection of short-term accounting-based bonus plans. Account Rev 64:758–772

    Google Scholar 

  • Nwaeze E, Yang S, Yin Q (2006) Accounting information and CEO compensation: the role of cash flow operations in the presence of earnings. Contemp Account Res 23:227–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phillips J (2003) Corporate tax-planning effectiveness: the role of compensation based incentives. Account Rev 78(3):847–874

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rego S, Wilson R (2008) Executive compensation, tax reporting aggressiveness and future firm performance. Working Paper University of Iowa

  • Rego S, Wilson R (2012) Equity risk incentives and corporate tax aggressiveness. J Account Res 50(3):775–810

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richardson V, Waegelein J (2002) The influence of long-term performance plans on earnings management and firm performance. Rev Quant Finance Account 18(2):161–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson J, Sikes S, Weaver C (2010) Performance measurements of corporate tax departments. Account Rev 85(May):1035–1064

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt A (2006) The persistence, forecasting, and valuation implications of the tax change component of earnings. Account Rev 81(3):589–616

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sloan R (1993) Accounting earnings and top executive compensation. J Account Econ 16(1–3):55–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson R (2009) An examination of corporate tax shelter participants. Account Rev 84(3):969–999

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thomas J. Lopez.

Appendices

Appendix 1

See Table 8.

Table 8 Control variable definitions

Appendix 2: tax-aggressiveness measures

To identify firms that have a propensity to engage in tax-aggressive behavior, we utilize three different proxies for tax aggressiveness. We discuss each of our measures below.

2.1 Permanent book-tax differences (PBTD)

Our first proxy is permanent book-tax differences (PBTD). PBTD measures aggressive tax reporting by focusing on permanent book-tax differences. Temporary book-tax differences frequently reflect book-tax differences that result from true differences in tax and financial reporting rules, rather than from actual tax planning (e.g., depreciation differences). Temporary book-tax differences may also reflect earnings management activity through the use of accruals, which is unrelated to tax planning. By removing these temporary differences PBTD produces a more accurate measure of true tax aggressiveness. We calculate PBTD as total book-tax differences less deferred tax expense grossed-up by the applicable federal statutory tax rate (Rego and Wilson 2008).

2.2 Discretionary permanent book-tax differences (DTAX)

Our second proxy for tax reporting aggressiveness is a measure of discretionary permanent book-tax differences (DTAX). Similar to PBTD, DTAX measures tax aggressiveness by focusing on permanent book-tax differences. DTAX improves upon the PBTD measure by including only discretionary permanent book-tax differences to measure tax aggressiveness. We calculate DTAX based on the work of Frank et al. (2009) who regress permanent book-tax differences on nondiscretionary items unrelated to tax planning that are known to cause permanent differences (see Eq. 8 below). We use the residuals (ε it ) from this equation as our estimate of discretionary permanent differences:

$${\text{PERMDIFF}}_{it} = \, \beta_{0} + \, \beta_{1} {\text{INTANG}}_{it} + \, \beta_{2} {\text{UNCON}}_{it} + \, \beta_{3} {\text{MI}}_{it} + \, \beta_{4} {\text{CSTE}}_{it} + \, \beta_{5} \Delta {\text{NOL}}_{it} + \, \beta_{6} {\text{LAGPERM}}_{it} + \, \varepsilon_{it}$$
(8)

where PERMDIFFi = total book-tax differences less temporary book-tax differences for firm i in year t, {BI it − [(CFTE it _CFOR it )/STR it ]} − (DTE it /STR it ); BI it  = pre-tax book income (#170) for firm i in year t; CFTE it  = current federal tax expense (#63) for firm i in year t; CFOR it  = current foreign tax expense (#64) for firm i in year t; DTE it  = deferred tax expense (#50) for firm i in year t; STR t  = statutory tax rate in year t; INTANG it  = goodwill and other intangibles (#33) for firm i in year t; UNCON it  = income (loss) reported under the equity method (#55) for firm i in year t; MI it  = income (loss) attributable to minority interest (#49) for firm i in year t; CSTE it  = current state income tax expense (#173) for firm i in year t; ∆NOL it  = change in net operating loss carryforwards (#52) for firm i in year t; LAGPERM it  = one-year lagged PERMDIFF for firm i in year t; and ε it  = discretionary permanent difference (DTAX it ) for firm i in year t.Footnote 11

All variables above are as defined in Frank et al. (2009).

2.3 Predicted tax shelter firms (SHELTER)

Our final measure of tax aggressiveness is SHELTER, a measure which identifies likely tax shelter participants. Wilson (2009) developed the predictive model using a sample of identified tax shelter participants. We use SHELTER to predict which of our sample firms are currently engaged in tax shelter activity (see Eq. 9). A firm’s tax shelter score (SCORE) is obtained by inserting firm specific variables into the model and using the estimated coefficients from Table 5 in Frank et al. (2009) as follows:

$${\text{SCORE }} = - 4.30 \, + \, 6.63 \, \times {\text{BTD }} + \, - 1.72 \, \times {\text{ LEV }} + \, 0.66 \, \times {\text{ SIZE }} + \, 2.26 \, \times {\text{ ROA }} + \, 1.62 \, \times {\text{ FOR\_INCOME }} + \, 1.56 \, \times {\text{ R}}\& {\text{D}}$$
(9)

All variables are as defined in Wilson (2009). SIZE is the log of total assets (data 6). LEV is long-term debt (data 9) divided by total assets. ROA is pre-tax earnings (data 170) divided by total assets. FOR_INCOME is (data 273) divided by lagged total assets. R&D is (data 46) divided by lagged total assets. BTD is book income less taxable income scaled by lagged total assets. Book income is pre-tax income (data 170). Taxable income is calculated by grossing up the sum of the current federal tax expense (data 63) and the current foreign tax expense (data 64) and subtracting the change in NOL Carryforward (data 52). If the current federal tax expense is missing, then total current tax expense is calculated by subtracting deferred taxes (data 50), state income taxes (data 173) and other income taxes (data 211) from total income taxes (data 16). The predicted probability of tax sheltering is then calculated as follows:

$${\text{P}}\left( {\text{SHELTER}} \right) = \, e^{{({\text{SCORE}})}} /(1 \, + e^{{({\text{SCORE}})}} )$$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hansen, V., Lopez, T.J. & Reitenga, A. The executive compensation implications of the tax component of earnings. Rev Quant Finan Acc 48, 557–595 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-016-0561-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-016-0561-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation