Skip to main content
Log in

Valuation of Reverse Mortgages with Default Risk Models

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Reverse mortgages are designed to offer additional sources of financing incomes to senior homeowners. In the United States, home equity conversion mortgages (HECMs) are nonrecourse reverse mortgage loans insured by the Federal Housing Administration (FHA). Based on a fairly recent stream of the reverse mortgage literature, the relatively high loan-to-value ratio has jeopardized the financial soundness of such contracts. In the wake of the 2008 financial crisis, rising property taxes and homeowner insurance defaults impaired HECM solvency; hence, policy changes were implemented to help prevent borrower default. In this paper, we propose a pricing solution which, as we demonstrate in the paper, effectively improves program solvency by fairly matching the benefits and liabilities of HECM participants. The methodology allows for customization of fair mortgage loan payments and premiums and improves program accessibility based on borrowers’ individual credit and default risk. Our proposed pricing solution and the corresponding newly designed rating system provide HECM policymakers with a better payment arrangement and offer important policy implications for the current HECM program. Rather than borrower property taxes and insurance delinquency, we demonstrate that the mispricing of HECM mortgage insurance premiums and the corresponding loan payments could be the primary reasons for program insolvency.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The HECM fact sheet is available at https://www.hud.gov/sites/documents/HECMREFORMFACTSHEET.PDF.

  2. The HECM financial assessment and property charge guide is available at https://www.hud.gov/sites/documents/16-10ML-ATCH.PDF.

  3. An introduction to the DBRS rating system is available at http://www.dbrs.com/research/230124/rating-reverse-mortgage-transactions-in-canada-archived.pdf.

  4. An introduction to Moody’s rating system is available at https://www.moodys.com/research/Moodys-publishes-global-methodology-for-rating-reverse-mortgage-securitizations--PR_325140.

References

  • Bardhan, A., Karapandža, R., & Urošević, B. (2006). Valuing mortgage insurance contracts in emerging market economies. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 32, 9–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauer, D., & Ruß, J. (2006). Pricing longevity bonds using implied survival probabilities, Unpublished working paper. University of Ulm.

  • Bielecki, TR, & Rutkowski, M. (2013). Credit risk: modeling valuation and hedging. New York: Springer Science & Business Media.

    Google Scholar 

  • Case, KE, & Shiller, RJ (1989). The efficiency of the market for single-family homes. American Economic Review, 79, 125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, H., Cox, S.H., & Wang, S.S. (2010). Is the Home Equity Conversion Mortgage in the United States sustainable? Evidence from pricing mortgage insurance premiums and non-recourse provisions using the conditional Esscher transform. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 46, 371–384.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, SH, & Lin, Y. (2007). Natural hedging of life and annuity mortality risks. North American Actuarial Journal, 11, 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davidoff, T. (2015). Can “high costs” justify weak demand for the Home Equity Conversion Mortgage? The Review of Financial Studies, 28, 2364–2398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davidoff, T., Gerhard, P., & Post, T. (2017). Reverse mortgages: What homeowners (don’t) know and how it matters. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 133, 151–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dickson, DC, Hardy, M., Hardy, MR, & Waters, H.R. (2013). Actuarial mathematics for life contingent risks. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duffie, D., & Singleton, KJ (1999). Modeling term structures of defaultable bonds. The Review of Financial Studies, 12, 687–720.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • FitchRatings. (2020). UK Equity-Release Mortgages: Capital strain is key risk for life insurers, Special Report.

  • Hao, C., Alam, MM, & Carling, K. (2010). Review of the literature on credit risk modeling: development of the past 10 years. Banks & Bank Systems, 43–60.

  • Haurin, D., Ma, C., Moulton, S., Schmeiser, M., Seligman, J., & Shi, W. (2016). Spatial variation in reverse mortgages usage: House price dynamics and consumer selection. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 53, 392–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heynderickx, W., Cariboni, J., Schoutens, W., & Smits, B. (2016). The relationship between risk-neutral and actual default probabilities: the credit risk premium. Applied Economics, 48, 4066–4081.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ito, T., & Hirono, KN. (1993). Efficiency of the Tokyo housing market, Technical Report, National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Jarrow, R. (1992). Credit risk: Drawing the analogy. Risk Magazine 5.

  • Jarrow, RA, & Turnbull, SM (1995). Pricing derivatives on financial securities subject to credit risk. The Journal of Finance, 50, 53–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ji, M., Hardy, M., & Li, J.S.-H. (2012). A semi-Markov multiple state model for reverse mortgage terminations. Annals of Actuarial Science, 6, 235–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kau, JB, Keenan, DC, Muller, WJ, & Epperson, J.F. (1992). A generalized valuation model for fixed-rate residential mortgages. Journal of Money Credit and Banking, 24, 279–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kogure, A., Li, J., & Kamiya, S. (2014). A Bayesian multivariate risk-neutral method for pricing reverse mortgages. North American Actuarial Journal, 18, 242–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, Y.-T., Kung, K.-L., & Liu, I.-C. (2018). Profitability and risk profile of reverse mortgages: A cross-system and cross-plan comparison. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 78, 255–266.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, Y.-T., Wang, C.-W., & Huang, H.-C. (2012). On the valuation of reverse mortgages with regular tenure payments. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 51, 430–441.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, JS-H, Hardy, MR, & Tan, K.S. (2010). On pricing and hedging the No-Negative-Equity guarantee in equity release mechanisms. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 77, 499–522.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin, Y., & Cox, SH (2005). Securitization of mortality risks in life annuities. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 72, 227–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, D. (2015). Hacking reverse mortgages, Unpublished paper, MIT.

  • Ma, S., & Deng, Y. (2013). Evaluation of reverse mortgage programs in Korea. Seoul Journal of Business 19.

  • Mayer, CJ, & Simons, KV (1994). Reverse mortgages and the liquidity of housing wealth. Real Estate Economics, 22, 235–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McLachlan, GJ, & McGiffin, D. (1994). On the role of finite mixture models in survival analysis. Statistical Methods in Medical Research, 3, 211–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton, RC, & Lai, RN. (2016). On an efficient design of reverse mortgages: A possible solution for aging Asian populations, Available at SSRN 3075087.

  • Miller, JJ, Nikaj, S., & Lee, J.M. (2019). Reverse mortgages and senior property tax relief. Journal of Housing Economics, 44, 26–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moulton, S., & Haurin, D. (2015). Reverse rortgages: Reducing financial risk while preserving access, macfound.org/HousingMatters.

  • Moulton, S., Haurin, D., & Shi, W. (2016). Reducing default rates of reverse mortgages. Center for Retirement Research.

  • Moulton, S., Haurin, DR, & Shi, W. (2015). An analysis of default risk in the Home Equity Conversion Mortgage (HECM) program. Journal of Urban Economics, 90, 17–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nothaft, FE, Gao, AH, & Wang, G.H. (1995). The stochastic behavior of the Freddie Mac-Fannie Mae conventional mortgage home price index. In Annual meeting of american real estate and urban economics association. Washington, DC.

  • Pu, M., Fan, G.-Z., & Deng, Y. (2014). Breakeven determination of loan limits for reverse mortgages under information asymmetry. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 48, 492–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shao, A.W., Hanewald, K., & Sherris, M. (2015). Reverse mortgage pricing and risk analysis allowing for idiosyncratic house price risk and longevity risk. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 63, 76–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharma, T., French, D., & McKillop, D. (2020). Risk and equity release mortgages in the UK. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 1–24.

  • Szymanoski, EJ, Enriquez, JC, & DiVenti, T.R. (2007). Home equity conversion mortgage terminations: Information to enhance the developing secondary market. Cityscape, 5–45.

  • Thomas, RG (2021). Valuation of no-negative-equity guarantees with a lower reflecting barrier. Annals of Actuarial Science, 15, 115–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, C. (2019). On the actuarial treatment of Equity Release Mortgages. https://craigturnbullfia.com/on-the-actuarial-treatment-of-equity-release-mortgages/. [Online; accessed 19-July-2021].

  • Wang, SS (2000). A class of distortion operators for pricing financial and insurance risks. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 67, 15–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Junsen Tang.

Ethics declarations

All authors certify that they have no affiliations with or involvement in any organization or entity with any financial interest or non-financial interest in the subject matter or materials discussed in this manuscript. Carole Bernard acknowledges funding from the FWO through an Odysseus research grant.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A: Revisiting the Parity Condition (6)

In “Fair Pricing Conditions for RM Guarantees”, we proposed the parity condition (6) for the MIP and annuity loan payment determination, which helps mitigate the HECM insolvency problem. In the following, we explain this parity condition from the perspectives of benefit and liability matching of all HECM participants. In presence of the event of death or default, the EPVs of the benefits and liabilities of the HECM program, its borrower, and the lender, are respectively given by

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \text{EPV of HECM benefits } \!&=&\!\text{EPV of MIPs}, \end{array} $$
(30)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \text{EPV of HECM liabilities} \!&=&\! \text{EPV of loss} + \text{EPV of rental incomes}, \end{array} $$
(31)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \text{EPV of borrower's benefits } \!&=&\! \text{I{\kern-.2pt}n{\kern-.2pt}i{\kern-.2pt}t{\kern-.2pt}i{\kern-.2pt}a{\kern-.2pt}l{\kern-.2pt} w{\kern-.2pt}i{\kern-.2pt}t{\kern-.2pt}h{\kern-.2pt}d{\kern-.2pt}r{\kern-.2pt}a{\kern-.2pt}w{\kern-.2pt}a{\kern-.2pt}l{\kern-.2pt}s{\kern-.2pt} + {\kern-.2pt} E{\kern-.2pt}P{\kern-.2pt}V{\kern-.2pt} o{\kern-.2pt}f{\kern-.2pt} a{\kern-.2pt}n{\kern-.2pt}n{\kern-.2pt}u{\kern-.2pt}i{\kern-.2pt}t{\kern-.2pt}y{\kern-.2pt} l{\kern-.2pt}o{\kern-.2pt}a{\kern-.2pt}n{\kern-.2pt} p{\kern-.2pt}a{\kern-.2pt}y{\kern-.2pt}m{\kern-.2pt}e{\kern-.2pt}n{\kern-.2pt}ts},\\ &&\!+ \text{EPV of rental incomes} \end{array} $$
(32)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \text{EPV of borrower's liabilities} \!&=&\! \text{EPV of house value - EPV of nonnegative balance} \\ \!&=&\! \text{$H(0)$} - \text{EPV of rental incomes} \\&&\!- \text{EPV of nonnegative balance}, \end{array} $$
(33)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \text{EPV of lender's benefits} \!&=&\! \text{EPV of loan accumulation}, \end{array} $$
(34)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \text{EPV of lender's liabilities} \!&=&\! \text{I{\kern-.2pt}n{\kern-.2pt}i{\kern-.2pt}t{\kern-.2pt}i{\kern-.2pt}a{\kern-.2pt}l{\kern-.2pt} wi{\kern-.2pt}t{\kern-.2pt}h{\kern-.2pt}d{\kern-.2pt}r{\kern-.2pt}a{\kern-.2pt}w{\kern-.2pt}a{\kern-.2pt}l{\kern-.2pt}s + EPV of annuity loan payments}\\ &&\!+ \text{EPV of MIPs} , \end{array} $$
(35)

with

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \text{EPV of loan accumulation} &=& \text{Initial withdrawals + EPV of interest charges}\\ && \text{ + EPV of MIPs} + \text{EPV of annuity payments}, \end{array} $$

and

$$ \text{EPV of house value} = H(0) - \text{EPV of rental incomes}. $$

Equations 30-35 can be explained as follows. On behalf of the borrower, a lender pays mortgage insurance premiums to the HECM program, which is committed to insuring the lender’s crossover risk. Throughout the contract, the HECM program is also liable for allowing the borrower to finance additional rental incomes by depreciation of her/his home appraisal. In addition to the HECM program’s rental financing, the borrower receives initial withdrawals and ongoing annuity loan payments from the lender until the contract terminates. At contract termination, the borrower transfers home ownership to fulfill her/his liability. The borrower only needs to repay the accumulated loan up to the amount of house value, with a rental financing discount. Then, the lender sells the collateral house to reclaim the loan. Any excess of the loan accumulation over the home sale is considered a nonnegative balance and thus is returned to the borrower. Since the presence of the HECM program immunizes the lender from the crossover risk, she/he receives full compensation from the HECM insurance fund for the loss caused by the crossover event. Therefore, the lender receives the loan repayment and profits from her/his interest charges.

By equating the sum of the EPV of benefits in Eqs. 3032 and 34 and the sum of the EPV of liabilities in Eqs. 3133 and 35, it follows that

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} H(0) &-& \text{EPV of rental incomes} = \text{Initial withdrawals + EPV of interest charges} \quad \\ &+& \text{EPV of annuity payments + EPV of MIPs + EPV of nonnegative balance} \\ &-& \text{EPV of loss}, \end{array} $$

which confirms the parity condition in Eqs. 5 and 6.

Appendix B: Proof of Theorem 3.1 and Derivation of Eq. 10

According to Bielecki and Rutkowski (2013), the processes, \(M_{t}^{\tau _{1}}:=\chi (t)-{\int \limits }_{0}^{t\wedge \tau _{1}}h(s)\left (1-\chi (t)\right )ds\) and \(M_{t}^{\tau _{2}}:=\gamma (t)-{\int \limits }_{0}^{t\wedge \tau _{2}}\mu _{x}(s)\left (1-\gamma (t)\right )ds\), are martingales with respect to their natural filtrations. We thus have \(\mathbb {E}^{\mathbb {Q}}\left [dM_{t}^{\tau _{1}}|\mathcal {F}_{t}\right ]=0\) and \(\mathbb {E}^{\mathbb {Q}}\left [dM_{t}^{\tau _{2}}|\mathcal {F}_{t}\right ]=0\) respectively. This implies that for any integrable adapted integrand g, we have

and

Therefore, by Fubini’s theorem and the mutual independence of τ1 and τ2, and the payoffs of Bal(t) and Loss(t), we can rewrite Eq. 9 as follows:

(36)

where L(0) = ω + p0H(0), h(t) and μx(t) are assumed to be nonstochastic. Equation 36 represents the different payoffs depending on the values of τ1 and τ2.

Note that

(37)

and

(38)

and

$$ e^{-rt}\mathbb{E}^{\mathbb{Q}} \left[H(t)\right]=e^{-\delta t}H(0). $$
(39)

Substituting (37), (38) and (39) into (36), it follows that

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} H(0) &=& L(0) + \delta H(0) \times {{\int}_{0}^{T}} {~}_{u} p_{x,m} \times {~}_{u} p_{x,d} \times e^{-\delta u} du \\ &&+ (r+\pi_{r}) \times {{\int}_{0}^{T}} e^{-ru} \times {~}_{u} p_{x,m} \times {~}_{u} p_{x,d} \times L(u)du + c \times {{\int}_{0}^{T}} e^{-ru} \\&&\times {~}_{u} p_{x,m} \times {~}_{u} p_{x,d} du \\ &&+ {{\int}_{0}^{T}} e^{-ru} \times \left( h(u)+\mu_{x}(u)\right) \times {~}_{u} p_{x,m} \times {~}_{u} p_{x,d} \times \mathbb{E}^{\mathbb{Q}}\left[Bal(u)\right] du. \end{array} $$

Furthermore, we use Fubini’s theorem and mutual independence to derive Eqs. 10 and 11. Substituting (37) and (38) into (10) and (11), it follows that

and

Thus, we have

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&p_{0} H(0) + p_{a} \times {{\int}_{0}^{T}} e^{-ru} \times {~}_{u} p_{x,d}\times{~}_{u} p_{x,m} \times L(u)du\\ &=& {{\int}_{0}^{T}} e^{-ru} \times \left( h(u)+\mu_{x}(u)\right) \times {~}_{u} p_{x,d} \times {~}_{u} p_{x,m}\times \mathbb{E}^{\mathbb{Q}} \left[Loss(u)\right]du, \end{array} $$

which completes the proof of Theorem 3.1.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bernard, C., Kolkiewicz, A. & Tang, J. Valuation of Reverse Mortgages with Default Risk Models. J Real Estate Finan Econ 66, 806–839 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-021-09862-0

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-021-09862-0

Keywords

Navigation