Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Decentralization, institutions, and maritime piracy

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Piracy is an organized crime that is not politically motivated; however, piracy has been linked consistently to the political environment and the quality of national institutions. Provincial governance considerations and spatial aspects may influence the emergence and sustainability of piratical activities. Unlike the extant literature, we investigate the impact of fiscal and political decentralization on the incidence of piracy, while accounting for the average distance to the coast of the nearest region to the pirate incident. Fiscal decentralization generally serves as a deterrent to piracy, while political decentralization may encourage or inhibit piracy. Political decentralization may deter piracy by providing policy ownership to local officials. Alternatively, decentralization may foster piracy by inhibiting interjurisdictional competition or by separating local governance from the national seat of power. In general, enhanced institutional quality limits piracy at both national and regional levels.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Smaller and more numerous bottom governing tiers can limit anti-piracy coordination if regions pool policing resources. Hence, the influence of the size of the bottom governing tiers on piracy is not unequivocal and must be empirically tested.

  2. Measurement error in the dependent variable might be an issue to the extent that some piracy cases go unreported. Unfortunately, we are not aware of a piracy dataset that is immune to this potential issue.

  3. Our first-stage regression results show that population density in 1500 has a negative and statistically significant effect on current institutions, confirming that the instrument is valid. This is similar to the findings by Acemoglu et al. (2002). They provide convincing arguments that differences in population density in 1500 among former colonies explain the different types of institutions that emerged in those countries. In sparsely populated locations, European colonizers were able or encouraged to settle in large numbers and introduce pro-development institutions. In densely populated areas, however, it was profitable for colonial powers to either maintain existing or introduce new extractive institutions. These “institutions of private property” and “extractive institutions” persisted over time till the present. For the excludability restriction, we assume that population density in 1500 is exogenous and its impact on piracy channels through institutions.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2002). Reversal of fortune: geography and institutions in the making of the modern world income distribution. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1231–1294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boulding, K. E. (1962). Conflict and defense: a general theory. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brancati, D. (2006). Decentralization: fueling the fire or dampening the flames of ethnic conflict and secessionism? International Organization, 60(3), 651–685.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. M. (1980). The power to tax: analytical foundations of a fiscal constitution. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buhaug, H., Cederman, L.-E., & Rød, J. K. (2008). Disaggregating ethno-nationalist civil wars: a dyadic test of exclusion theory. International Organization, 62(3), 531–551.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buhaug, H., & Rød, J. K. (2006). Local determinants of African civil wars, 1970–2001. Political Geography, 25(3), 315–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cederman, L.-E., Buhaug, H., & Rød, J. K. (2009). Ethno-nationalist dyads and civil war: a GIS-based approach. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 53(4), 496–525.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coggins, B. L. (2012). Global patterns of maritime piracy, 2000–2009: introducing a new dataset. Journal of Peace Research, 49(4), 605–617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daxecker, U. E., & Prins, B. C. (2013). Insurgents of the sea: institutional and economic opportunities for maritime piracy. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 57(6), 940–965.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daxecker, U. E., & Prins, B. C. (2015a). Searching for sanctuary: government power and the location of maritime piracy. International Interactions, 41(4), 699–717.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daxecker, U. E., & Prins, B. C. (2015b). Enforcing order: territorial reach and maritime piracy. Conflict Management and Peace Science. doi:10.1177/0738894215594756.

    Google Scholar 

  • Daxecker, U. E., & Prins, B. C. (2015c). The new barbary wars: forecasting maritime piracy. Foreign Policy Analysis, 11(1), 23–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daxecker, U. E. & Prins, B. C. (2015d). The Maritime piracy location and event data (MPELD). Unpublished manuscript.

  • de Groot, O. J., Rablen, M. D., & Shortland, A. (2011). Gov-aargh-nance—“even criminals need law and order.” Centre for Economic Development and Institutions (CEDI), Working Paper No 11–01, Brunel University, West London. Retrieved February 26, 2016 from http://cedi.org.uk.

  • Dreher, A., & Fischer, J. A. V. (2010). Government decentralization as a disincentive for transnational terror? An empirical analysis. International Economic Review, 51(4), 981–1002.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fan, C. S., Lin, C., & Treisman, D. (2009). Political decentralization and corruption: evidence from around the world. Journal of Public Economics, 93(1–2), 14–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gennaioli, N., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2013). Human capital and regional development. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(1), 105–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hastings, J. V. (2009). Geographies of state failure and sophistication in maritime piracy hijackings. Political Geography, 28(3), 213–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Country Risk Guide (ICRG). (2015). The Political Risk Services (PRS) Group. Retrieved April 14, 2016 from https://www.prsgroup.com/.

  • International Maritime Bureau (IMB). (2015). Piracy and armed robbery against ships, report for 1 January–31 December 2014. London: International Maritime Bureau.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund. (2015). Government Finance Statistics. Retrieved April 4, 2016 from http://www.imf.org/.

  • Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2010). The Worldwide Governance Indicators: A summary of methodology, data and analytical issues, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No 5430. World Bank: Washington, DC.

  • Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1995). Institutions and economic performance: cross-country tests using alternative institutional measures. Economics and Politics, 7(3), 207–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2007). An-aargh-chy: the law and economics of pirate organization. Journal of Political Economy, 115(6), 1049–1094.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2009). The calculus of piratical consent: the myth of the myth of social contract. Public Choice, 139(3), 443–459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2010). Pirational choice: the economics of infamous pirate practices. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 76(4), 497–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2014). Pirates, prisoners, and preliterates: anarchic context and the private enforcement of law. European Journal of Law and Economics, 37(3), 365–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1996). The puzzle of Indian democracy: a consociational interpretation. The American Political Science Review, 90(2), 258–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lustik, I. S., Miodownik, D., & Eidelson, R. J. (2004). Secessionism in multicultural states: does sharing power prevent or encourage it? The American Political Science Review, 98(2), 209–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, M. G. (2014). Major episodes of political violence (MEPV) and conflict regions, 19462014. Center for Systemic Peace. Retrieved December 14, 2014 from http://www.systemicpeace.org

  • Murphy, M. N. (2007). Contemporary piracy and maritime terrorism: the threat to international security, Adelphi Paper No. 338. International Institute for Strategic Studies: London.

  • Naftalin, M. (2013). In the same boat? Contrasting piracy in West and East Africa. ISN ETH Zurich. Retrieved February 27, 2016 from http://www.neptunemaritimesecurity.com/in-the-same-boat-contrasting-piracy-in-west-and-east-africa/.

  • National Consortium for the Study of Terrorism and Responses to Terrorism (START). (2013). Global terrorism database (GTD). Retrieved February 3, 2014 from www.start.umd.edu/gtd/.

  • Percy, S., & Shortland, A. (2013). The business of piracy in Somalia. The Journal of Strategic Studies, 36(4), 541–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piazza, J. A. (2011). Poverty, minority economic discrimination, and domestic terrorism. Journal of Peace Research, 48(3), 339–353.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prins, B. C., Daxecker, U. E., & Sanford, A. (2014). Terror on the seas: assessing the threat of modern day piracy. The SAIS Review of International Affairs. Retrieved February 26, 2016 from http://www.saisreview.org/2014/02/10/terror-on-the-seas-assessing-the-threat-of-modern-day-piracy.

  • Rustad, S. C. A., Buhaug, H., Falch, A., & Gates, S. (2011). All conflict is local: modeling sub-national variation in civil conflict risk. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 28(1), 15–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shortland, A., & Vothknecht, M. (2011). Combating “marine terrorism” off the coast of Somalia. European Journal of Political Economy, 27(S1), S133–S151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64(5), 416–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Treves, T. (2009). Piracy, law of the sea, and the use of force: developments off the coast of Somalia. The European Journal of International Law, 20(2), 399–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2014a). World development indicators. Retrieved August 2, 2015 from http://databank.worldbank.org/.

  • World Bank. (2014b). Worldwide governance indicators. Retrieved August 2, 2015 from http://www.govindicators.org.

Download references

Acknowledgments

This paper has profited from comments from William F. Shughart II and an anonymous referee. The authors’ research was supported by the Vibhooti Shukla Endowment.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Todd Sandler.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (DOC 304 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gaibulloev, K., Sandler, T. Decentralization, institutions, and maritime piracy. Public Choice 169, 357–374 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-016-0346-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-016-0346-3

Keywords

Navigation