Skip to main content
Log in

Concerns for Long-Run Risks and Natural Resource Policy

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The legislature in many countries requires that short-run risk and long-run risk be considered in making natural resource policy. In this paper, we explore this issue by analyzing how natural resource conservation policy should optimally respond to long-run risks in a resource management framework where the social evaluator has (Duffie and Epstein in Econometrica 60:353–394, 1992; Schroder and Skiadas in J Econ Theory 89:68–126, 1999) continuous-time stochastic recursive preferences. The response of resource conservation policy to long-run risks is reflected into a matrix whose coefficients measure precaution toward short-run risk, long-run risk and covariance risk. Attitudes toward the temporal resolution of risk underly concerns for long-run risks as well as the response of resource conservation policy to future uncertainty. We formally compare the responses of natural resource policy to long-run risks under recursive utility and under time-additive expected utility. A stronger preference for early resolution of uncertainty can prompt a more conservative resource policy as a response to long-run risks. In the very particular case where the social evaluator preferences are represented by a standard time-additive expected utility, long-run risks are not factored in resource conservation policy decisions. Our work also contributes to the so-called Hotelling Puzzle by formally showing that the fundamental Hotelling’s homogeneous resource depletion problem (one without extraction costs, without new discoveries, and without technical progress) can lead to a decreasing shadow price when attitudes toward the temporal resolution of risk are accounted for.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In the financial sector, for instance, a growing attention to issues related to natural capital depletion is reflected in the 2012 Natural Capital Declaration (NCD), the 2017 Network of Central Banks and Supervisors for Greening the Financial System (NGFS), and the United Nations Principles for Responsible Investment (UN-PRI). The concept of natural capital defines the global stock of natural resources, including renewable resources such as clean air, water, soil, and living things, or non-renewable resources, such as minerals and fossil fuels (Arrow et al. 2012, 2004; Daily et al. 2000; Dasgupta 1990; Pearce 1988).

  2. For instance, accounting for concerns for long-run risks has provided a reconciliation of the so-called equity premium puzzle with financial theory. See, for instance, Epstein et al. (2014), Bansal (2007), Bansal and Yaron (2004), Sargent (2007), Brown and Kim (2014), Bansal et al. (2010), Bansal and Ochoa (2011), Strzalecki (2013), CóRdoba and Ripoll (2016). In the economics of longevity literature, CóRdoba and Ripoll (2016) analyze how attitudes toward the temporal resolution of uncertainty affect the value of statistical life (VSL) by calibrating a version of a discrete-time recursive utility framework.

  3. See, for instance, Pindyck (1980), Epaulard and Pommeret (2003), Dasgupta and Heal (1974), Howitt et al. (2005), Knapp and Olson (1996), Young and Ryan (1996), Lewis (1977), Sundaresan (1984), Ackerman et al. (2013), Bansal and Ochoa (2011), Peltola and Knapp (2001), Pindyck (2007), Bansal et al. (2016).

  4. Natural resource stocks are increasingly analyzed as natural capital that provides a flow of valuable goods and services over time (Arrow et al. 2012, 2004; Daily et al. 2000; Dasgupta 1990).

  5. To keep matters as simple as possible, we have not admitted a role for technology. However, allowing a role for technology will not change the main insights brought out by this paper.

  6. Thanks to an anonymous reviewer for suggesting this section.

  7. The function N(.) is assumed to be differentiable, linear or concave.

  8. A standard assumption in the aggregate biomass approach to modeling natural resource dynamics in a stochastic setting is that the growth of the resource can be represented as a stochastic Itô differential equation. To keep matters as simple as possible, the volatility does not depend of the size natural resource stock and is assumed to be additive. See Pindyck (1980) for a similar assumption. This specification of the dynamics of uncertainty does not prevent other forms of uncertainty dynamics to be analyzed. The point here is to allow unexpected shocks on the evolution of the natural resource over time.

  9. The Duffie and Epstein (1992) recursive utility is the continuous-time analog of the Epstein and Zin (1989) discrete-time recursive utility (Kraft and Seifried 2014). Using a discrete-time recursive utility would generally make the optimal stochastic dynamic analysis less tractable. The continuous-time approach offers analytical advantages and approximation gets less necessary. As mentioned by Cochrane (2005a), using a continuous-time approach often allows obtaining analytical results that would be unavailable in discrete time.

  10. Allowing the aggregator f(xV) to satisfy certain continuity-Lipschitz-growth type conditions ensure the existence of the recursive utility (Duffie and Epstein 1992, p. 366).

  11. An alternative way to express the integral Eq. (2) is to view it as the solution of the stochastic differential equation \(dV(t)=-f(x(t),V(t))dt+\sigma _{V}(t)dB(t),\) where \(\sigma _{V}(t)\) is the volatility of the future utility index, given the information available at time t.

  12. For ease of notation, throughout, we shortly use V(t) to refer to V(S(t)), and f(t) to refer to f(x(t), V(t)), unless otherwise stated. The Bellman’s characterization of optimality with a continuous-time recursive utility is shown by Duffie and Epstein (1992, proposition 9). Some general theorems on the existence and the unicity of the solution to the Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman equation require that the aggregator or both the drift coefficient and the diffusion coefficient of the state variable satisfy certain continuity-Lipschitz-growth types conditions. See, for instance, Duffie and Lions (1992), Schroder and Skiadas (1999).

  13. For the sake of illustration, Fig. 3 in “Appendix 5” displays a numerical computation of the stationary equilibrium of the natural problem resource policy with a Schroder and Skiadas (1999) recursive utility and a nonlinear natural resource stock-growth function. We developed a numerical algorithm (5 pages in length) for computing the stationary equilibrium of the resource problem. The algorithm is available upon request.

  14. In addition, V must satisfy another a transversality, condition of the form

    $$\begin{aligned} \lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }V_{S}(t)S(t)=0. \end{aligned}$$
  15. Convexity of the intertemporal aggregator in the future utility index expresses a preference for early resolution of uncertainty while concavity of the intertemporal aggregator in the future utility index expresses a preference for late resolution of uncertainty. Later in Sect. 4, we will assume a Schroder and Skiadas (1999) parametric form of the aggregator that simplifies the exposition of this point.

  16. To illustrate the concept of temporal resolution of uncertainty, let us consider the following three options: In the first option, a coin is flipped in each future date. If heads you get a high consumption payoff and if tails a low one. In the second option, a coin is flipped once. If heads you get a high consumption payoff in all future dates and if tails you get a low one in all future dates . In a third option all the coins are tossed at once in the first period, but the timing of the payoffs being the same as in the other two options. A decision maker may not be indifferent about the three options. A decision maker may prefer a late resolution of uncertainty or an early resolution of uncertainty as a result of his/her attitudes toward correlation of payoffs across periods, long-run uncertainty (Duffie and Epstein 1992).

  17. The future utility risk channel embedded in the natural resource policy-making process resembles the “wealth risk” channel mentioned by Sandmo (1970) in financial risk management decisions.

  18. The function trace(A) of a square matrix A is defined to be the sum of its diagonal elements.

  19. Using a different framework, a study by Shogren and Crocker (1992) emphasized the role of endogenous risk inherent in managing environmental and natural resource issues.

  20. Thanks to an anonymous reviewer for emphasizing this point.

  21. The importance of information gathering regarding long-run future trends affecting natural resource dynamics was mentioned by Solow (1974). As concerns over future environmental uncertainty grow, we believe it will become increasingly important to adopt an interdisciplinary approach while incorporating discussions on long-run risks in policy arenas. To give an example, it might be worthwhile revising and broadening the concept of forward-looking information, as defined by SEC (1994) in financial markets, to include endogenous long-run risk factors in environmental and natural resource problems.

  22. Indeed, the derivative of the trace function for the product of two matrices is given by:

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \, trace\Big ({\mathcal {W}}_{f}(t)\Sigma (t)\Big )}{\partial \Sigma (t)}=transpose ({\mathcal {W}}_{f}(t))={\mathcal {W}}_{f}(t). \end{aligned}$$

    The transpose of a matrix is a new matrix whose rows are the columns of the original (which makes its columns the rows of the original).

  23. This notion of prudence was first defined by Kimball (1990) as the sensitivity of the optimal choice to risk. The coefficient of absolute prudence of Kimball (1990) is defined as the ratio between the third derivative and the second derivative of the current utility function, while the coefficient of relative prudence is defined as absolute prudence, multiplied by the extraction rate.

  24. When \(\gamma =0\), this aggregator becomes \(f(x,V)=(1+\alpha V)\left[ log(x)-\frac{\beta }{\alpha }log(1+\alpha V)\right]\). The proof of the existence of the Schroder and Skiadas (1999) stochastic recursive utility relies on the theory of backward stochastic differential equations (BSDE).

  25. As already mentioned, the concept of temporal resolution of uncertainty can be intuitively depicted by considering the following three options: In the first option, a coin is flipped in each future date. If heads you get a high consumption payoff and if tails a low one. In the second option, a coin is flipped once. If heads you get a high consumption payoff in all future dates and if tails you get a low one in all future dates . In a third option all the coins are tossed at once in the first period, but the timing of the payoffs being the same as in the other two options. A decision maker may not be indifferent about the three options. A decision maker may prefer a late resolution of uncertainty or an early resolution of uncertainty as a result of his/her attitudes toward correlation of payoffs across periods, long-run uncertainty (Duffie and Epstein 1992).

  26. There is a connection between preferences for the timing of resolution of uncertainty and preferences for information (Skiadas 1998).

  27. The concept of aversion to long-run risk is similar to the concept of correlation aversion of payoffs across time periods (Strzalecki 2013; Duffie and Epstein 1992). The idea of correlation aversion was first discussed by Richard (1975). Along the same lines, see Crainich et al. (2013).

  28. The role of the parameter \(\alpha\) in capturing aversion to long-run risks may be connected to the second component of the Swanson (2012, proposition 1) decomposition, which is related to risk aversion toward future utility flows in a stochastic environment with recursive utility.

  29. With a time-additive expected utility, there is a sense that long-run risks are irrelevant to the social evaluator. An intuitive connection can be made with the concept of risk independence defined on multiattributed utility functions by Fishburn (1965), Keeney (1973), Pollak (1973). Broadly this research agenda shows that risk independence implies that the utility function is additive.

  30. More formally, it is assumed that at time t the positive semi-definite matrices \(\Sigma (t)\) and \({\tilde{\Sigma }}(t)\) are equal. In other words, at time t the following equality is satisfied:

    $$\begin{aligned} \left( \begin{array}{ccc} \sigma _{x}^{2}(t) &{} \sigma _{xV}(t) \\ &{}\\ \sigma _{xV}(t) &{} \sigma _{V}^{2}(t) \\ \end{array} \right) = \left( \begin{array}{ccc} \sigma _{{\tilde{x}}}^{2}(t) &{} \sigma _{{\tilde{x}}{\tilde{V}}}(t) \\ &{}\\ \sigma _{{\tilde{x}}{\tilde{V}}}(t) &{} \sigma _{{\tilde{V}}}^{2}(t) \\ \end{array} \right) .\end{aligned}$$
  31. In Pindyck (1980)’s framework, for instance, assuming a homogeneous resource stock (with zero extraction cost), would reduce Pindyck (1980, Eq. (15) and (17)) to the basic Hotelling (1931) rule, which requires the shadow price of the resource to grow over time at the discount rate.

  32. In addition, the value function V(t) must satisfy a transversality condition of the form

    $$\begin{aligned} \lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }e^{-\nu t}E\left( |V(t)|\right) =0, \end{aligned}$$

    for a suitable constant \(\nu\). See Duffie and Epstein (1992) for details.

  33. Our paper is the first to derive this exact analytical solution to the stochastic resource extraction problem with the Schroder and Skiadas (1999) recursive utility.

  34. While the discount rate and risk preferences are two differently defined concepts, a closer look at the third expression on the right-hand side of Eq. (54) shows that the discount rate does affect the premium for temporal resolution of uncertainty in the shadow pricing of the natural resource. More precisely, increasing the discount rate (\(\beta\)) negatively affects the premium for temporal resolution of uncertainty when \(\alpha >0\), whereas it positively affects the premium for temporal resolution of uncertainty when \(\alpha <0.\)

  35. This result contrasts with most of the theoretical works on non-renewable resources suggesting that the shadow price increases as a resource is depleted. For instance, Pindyck (1980) implicitly assumes indifference to the timing of resolution of uncertainty, implying that under uncertainty the shadow price of the resource (case of zero or linear cost of extraction) would exhibit an increasing trend.

  36. The aggregator would correspond to that of the time-additive expected utility, \(f(x,V)=u(x)-\beta V\), with \(u(x)=\frac{x^{\gamma }}{\gamma }.\)

  37. Under certainty, the Schroder and Skiadas (1999) aggregator reduces to \(f(x,V)=\frac{x^{\gamma }}{\gamma }-\beta V.\)

  38. The set of parameters for which the expected rate of change of the resource shadow price equals zero is not unique. Another example is \(\beta =3\%\), \(\gamma =0.11\), \(\alpha =6.2291\), and \(\sigma =1\). Their corresponding extraction ratio is 0.0077

  39. Our results reinforce the call by Shaw and Woodward (2008) who urged economists working on environmental and resource economics problems to pay attention to alternative models to time-additive expected utility as they have the potential to explain puzzling outcomes. An interesting line of future research would be to explore the role played by attitudes toward the temporal of uncertainty in rationalizing the absence of the basic Hotelling price path observed in cap-trade markets (Aldy and Armitage 2020).

  40. On a larger scale, some recent empirical studies document differences in risk preferences across countries (Rieger et al. 2015; Falk et al. 2018).

  41. While this paper modeling has focused on natural capital management issues, in future work we plan to extend and adapt a similar approach to investigate long-run risks issues involved in other areas of economics including intergenerational fiscal policy policies under future uncertainty.

  42. In other words, \(\Psi (t)\) is a vector with 2 rows and 1 column.

  43. The algorithm—5 pages in length—is not included here for reasons of conciseness, but is available upon request.

  44. The seminal paper by Barles and Souganidis (1990) uses the concept of viscosity solutions to provide convergence results for numerical approximation of Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman (HJB) equations.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Akcigit U, Hanley D, Kerr W (2016) Transition to clean technology. J Polit Econ 124:52–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Achdou Y, Han J, Lasry J, Lions P, Moll B (2021) Income and wealth distribution in macroeconomics: a continuous-time approach. Rev Econ Stud 89:45–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ackerman F, Stanton EA, Bueno R (2013) Epstein-Zin utility in DICE: is risk aversion irrelevant to climate policy? Environ Resource Econ 56:73–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aguilera R, Capapé J, Santiso J (2016) Sovereign wealth funds: a strategic governance view. Acad Manag Perspect 30:5–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aldy J, Armitage S (2020) The cost-effectiveness implications of carbon price certainty. AEA Papers Proc 110:113–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson S, Kellogg R, Salant S (2014) Hotelling under pressure. J Polit Econ 126:984–1026

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow K, Dasgupta P, Goulder L, Daily G, Ehrlich P, Heal G, Levin S, Maler K, Schneider S, Starrett D, Walker B (2004) Are we consuming too much? J Econ Perspect 18:147–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow K, Dasgupta P, Goulder L, Mumford K, Oleson K (2012) Sustainability and the measurement of wealth. Environ Dev Econ 17:317–353

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Augustin P, Tédongap R (2021) Disappointment aversion, term structure, and predictability puzzles in bond markets. Manage Sci 67:5969–6627

    Google Scholar 

  • Bansal R (2007) Long run risks and financial markets. The Review, St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank 89:283–300

    Google Scholar 

  • Bansal R, Ochoa M (2011) Temperature, aggregate risk, and expected returns. NBER Working Papers 17575, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc

  • Bansal R, Yaron A (2004) Risks for the long run: a potential resolution of asset pricing puzzles. J Financ 59:1481–1509

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bansal R, Kiku D, Yaron A (2010) Long run risks, the macroeconomy, and asset prices. Am Econ Rev 100:542–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bansal R, Kiku D, Ochoa M (2016) Climate change and growth risks. Working Paper 23009, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Barles G, Souganidis P (1990) Convergence of approximation schemes for fully nonlinear second order equations. In: 29th IEEE conference on decision and control, vol 4, pp 2347–2349

  • Barnett M, Brock W, Hansen L (2020) Pricing uncertainty induced by climate change. Rev Financ Stud 33:1024–1066

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown A, Kim H (2014) Do individuals have preferences used in macro-finance models? An experimental investigation. Manag Sci 60:939–958

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cai Y, Lontzek T (2019) The social cost of carbon with economic and climate risks. J Polit Econ 127:2684–2734

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cai Y, Judd K, Lontzek T (2017) The social cost of carbon with economic and climate risk. Economics Working Paper 18113, Hoover Institution

  • Cairns RD, Davis GA (2001) Adelman’s rule and the petroleum firm. Energy J 22:31–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cairns RD, Davis GA (2015) Mineral depletion and the rules of resource dynamics. Energy J 36:159–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carney M (2015) Breaking the tragedy of the horizon-climate change and financial stability. Speech given at Lloyd’s of London

  • Carney M (2016) Resolving the climate paradox. Arthur Burns Memorial Lecture, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang F (2004) Stochastic optimization in continuous time. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Chen X, Favilukis J, Ludvigson S (2013) An estimation of economic models with recursive preferences. Quant Econ 4:39–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark C (1976) Mathematical bioeconomics: the optimal management of renewable resources. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane (2005a) Asset pricing, Revised. Princeton University Press, Princeton

  • Cochrane J (2005b) Financial markets and the real economy. NBER Working Papers 11193, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc

  • CóRdoba J, Ripoll M (2016) Risk aversion and the value of life. Rev Econ Stud 84:1472–1509

    Google Scholar 

  • Crainich D, Eeckhoudt L, Le Courtois O (2013) An Index of (absolute) correlation aversion: theory and some implications. Working Papers 2013-ECO-12, IESEG School of Management

  • Crank J, Nicolson P (1974) A practical method for numerical evaluation of solutions of partial differential equations of the heat-conduction type. Math Proc Camb Philos Soc 43:50–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daily G, Söderqvist T, Aniyar S, Arrow K, Dasgupta P, Ehrlich P, Folke C, Jansson A, Jansson B, Kautsky N, Levin S, Lubchenco J, Mäler K, Simpson D, Starrett D, Tilman D, Walker B (2000) The value of nature and the nature of value. Science 289:395–396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daniel K, Litterman R, Wagner G (2019) Declining CO2 price paths. Proc Natl Acad Sci 116:20886–20891

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta P (1990) The environment as a commodity. Oxf Rev Econ Policy 6:51–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta P (2005) Three conceptions of intergenerational justice. In: Lillehammer H, Mellor DH (eds) Ramsey’s legacy. Clarendon Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta P (2008) Discounting climate change. J Risk Uncertain 37:141–169

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta P (2010a) 20th anniversary of EAERE: the European association of environmental and resource economists. Environ Resource Econ 46:135–137

  • Dasgupta P (2010b) The Concept of Natural Capital, Tech. rep., University of Cambridge, notes prepared for a lecture on the Concept of Natural Capital to be given at the Inter Academy Panel Biodiversity Conference on Integrating Ecosystem Services into Biodiversity Management, to be held at the Royal Society, January 13–14, 2010

  • Dasgupta P, Heal G (1974) The optimal depletion of exhaustible resources. Rev Econ Stud 41:3–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta H, Heal G (1979) Economic theory and exhaustible resources. James Nisbet and Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis GA, Cairns RD (1998) Simple analytics of valuing producing petroleum reserves. Energy J 19:133–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dawid H, Kopel M (1999) On optimal cycles in dynamic programming models with convex return function. Econ Theor 13:309–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Douenne T (2020) Disaster risks, disaster strikes, and economic growth: the role of preferences. Rev Econ Dyn 38:251–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drèze J, Stern N (1990) Policy reform, shadow prices, and market prices. J Public Econ 42:1–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duffie D, Epstein L (1992) Stochastic differential utility. Econometrica 60:353–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duffie D, Lions P (1992) PDE solutions of stochastic differential utility. J Math Econ 21:577–606

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engle R, Giglio S, Kelly B, Lee H, Stroebel J (2020) Hedging climate change news. Rev Financ Stud 33:1184–1216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • English MR (2000) Who Are the Stakeholders in environmental risk decisions?... How should they be involved? Risk Health Saf Environ 11:243–254

    Google Scholar 

  • Epaulard A, Pommeret A (2003) Recursive utility, endogenous growth, and the welfare cost of volatility. Rev Econ Dyn 6:672–684

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein L, Zin S (1989) Substitution, risk aversion and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: a theoretical framework. Econometrica 57:937–969

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein L, Farhi E, Strzalecki T (2014) How much would you pay to resolve long-run risk? Am Econ Rev 104:2680–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk A, Becker A, Dohmen T, Enke B, Huffman D, Sunde U (2018) Global evidence on economic preferences*. Q J Econ 133:1645–1692

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Femminis G (2001) Risk-sharing and growth: the role of precautionary savings in the “education’’ model. Scand J Econ 103:63–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischhoff B (1990) Understanding long-term environmental risks. J Risk Uncertain 3:315–330

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn P (1965) Independence in utility theory with whole product sets. Oper Res 13:28–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaudet G (2007) Natural resource economics under the rule of hotelling. Can J Econ 40:1033–1059

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaudet G, Howitt P (1989) A note on uncertainty and the hotelling rule, journal of environmental economics and management. J Environ Econ Manag 16:80–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gauteplass A, Skonhoft A (2014) Optimal exploitation of a renewable resource with capital limitations: nordic sheep farming with and without grazing externalities. Eur Rev Agric Econ 42:25–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halland H, Gelb A, Tordo S, Arfaa N, Smith G (2014) Sovereign wealth funds and long-term development finance: risks and opportunities. World Bank Working Paper

  • Halvorsen R, Smith T (1984) On measuring natural resource scarcity. J Polit Econ 92:954–964

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hambel C, Kraft H, Schwartz E (2015) Optimal carbon abatement in a stochastic equilibrium model with climate change. NBER Working Paper 0210449, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Hamilton JD (2009) Understanding crude oil prices. Energy J 30:179–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen L (2010) Recursive valuation and sentiments. Bendheim lectures, Princeton University, princeton Bendheim Lectures in Finance: Exploring Links Between Asset Pricing and Macroeconomic Modeling. Available at http://home.uchicago.edu/~lhansen/princeton1.pdf

  • Hansen L (2012) Dynamic valuation decomposition within stochastic economies. Econometrica 80:911–967

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart R, Spiro D (2011) The elephant in Hotelling’s room. Energy Policy 39:7834–7838

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hartzell-Nichols L (2012) Intergenerational risks. In: Roeser S, Hillerbrand R, Sandin P, Peterson M (eds) Handbook of risk theory. Springer, Netherlands, pp 931–960

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hayashi T, Miao J (2011) Intertemporal substitution and recursive smooth ambiguity preferences. Theor Econ 6:423–472

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heal G, Millner A (2014) Reflections uncertainty and decision making in climate change economics. Rev Environ Econ Policy 8:120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling H (1931) The economics of exhaustible resources. J Polit Econ 39:137–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Howitt R, MSangi S, Reynaud A, Knapp K (2005) Estimating intertemporal preferences for natural resource allocation. Am J Agric Econ 5:969–983

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen S, Traeger C (2014) Optimal climate change mitigation under long-term growth uncertainty: stochastic integrated assessment and analytic findings. Eur Econ Rev 69:104–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Judd K (1998) Numerical methods in economics, no. 0262100711 in MIT Press Books. The MIT Press, Cambridge

  • Kakeu J, Bouaddi M (2017) Empirical evidence of news about future prospects in the risk-pricing of oil assets. Energy Econ 64:458–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keeney R (1973) Risk independence and multiattributed utility functions. Econometrica 41:27–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khademvatani A, Gordon D (2013) A marginal measure of energy efficiency: the shadow value. Energy Econ 38:153–159

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimball M (1990) Precautionary saving in the small and in the large. Econometrica 58:53–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knapp KC, Olson L (1996) Dynamic resource management: intertemporal substitution and risk aversion. Am J Agric Econ 78:1004–1014

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koopmans T (1960) Stationary ordinal utility and impatience. Econometrica 28:287–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kraft H, Seifried F (2014) Stochastic differential utility as the continuous-time limit of recursive utility. J Econ Theory 151:528–550

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krautkraemer J (1998) Nonrenewable resource scarcity. J Econ Lit 36:2065–2107

    Google Scholar 

  • Kreps D, Porteus E (1978) Temporal resolution of uncertainty and dynamic choice theory. Econometrica 46:185–200

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levhari D, Mirman L (1980) The Great Fish war: an example using a dynamic cournot-nash solution. Bell J Econ 11:322–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis T (1977) Attitudes towards risk and the optimal exploitation of an exhaustible resource. J Environ Econ Manag 4:111–119

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin C-Y, Wagner G (2007) Steady-state growth in a Hotelling model of resource extraction. J Environ Econ Manag 54:68–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Livernois J (2009) On the empirical significance of the Hotelling rule. Rev Environ Econ Policy 3:22–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lontzek T, Narita D (2011) Risk-averse mitigation decisions in an unpredictable climate system*. Scand J Econ 113:937–958

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luo Y, Young E (2016) Long-run consumption risk and asset allocation under recursive utility and rational inattention. J Money Credit Bank 48:325–362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lybbert T, McPeak J (2012) Risk and intertemporal substitution: livestock portfolios and off-take among Kenyan pastoralists. J Dev Econ 97:415–426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merks R, Hoekstra A, Kaandorp J, Sloot P (2003) Models of coral growth: spontaneous branching, compactification and the Laplacian growth assumption. J Theor Biol 224:153–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • NAPA (1997) Deciding for the future: balancing risks and benefits fairly across generations. Tech, Rep. l-57744-050-1, National Academy of Public Administration. A Report for the US Departement of Energy

  • Nyarko Y, Olson L (1994) Stochastic growth when utility depends on both consumption and the stock level. Econ Theor 4:791–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ocampo J, Cosbey A, Khor M (2011) The transition to a green economy: benefits, challenges and risks from a sustainable development perspective, Working papers, Division for Sustainable Development. United Nations Environment Programme, report by a Panel of Experts to Second Preparatory Committee Meeting for United Nations Conference on Sustainable Development

  • Olson L, Roy S (2006) Theory of stochastic optimal economic growth. In: Dana R-A, Le Van C, Mitra T, Nishimura K (eds) Handbook on optimal growth. Springer, Berlin, pp 297–335

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Passmore G, Brown CG (1991) Analysis of rangeland degradation using stochastic dynamic programming. Aust J Agric Econ 35:131–157

    Google Scholar 

  • Pearce D (1988) Economics, equity and sustainable development. Futures 20:598–605, special Issue Sustainable Development

  • Peltola J, Knapp K (2001) Recursive preferences in forest management. For Sci 47:455–465

    Google Scholar 

  • Pindyck R (1980) Uncertainty and exhaustible resource markets. J Polit Econ 88:1203–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pindyck RS (2007) Uncertainty in environmental economics. Rev Environ Econ Policy 1:45–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pindyck R (2010) Fat tails, thin tails, and climate change policy. Working Papers 1012, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Center for Energy and Environmental Policy Research

  • Pohl W, Schmedders K, Wilms O (2018) Higher order effects in asset pricing models with long-run risks. J Financ 73:1061–1111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pohl W, Schmedders K, Wilms O (2021) Asset pricing with heterogeneous agents and long-run risk. J Financ Econ 140:941–964

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pollak RA (1973) The risk independence axiom. Econometrica 41:35–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rankin N (1998) How does uncertainty about future fiscal policy affect current macroeconomic variables? Scand J Econ 100:473–494

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richard S (1975) Multivariate risk aversion, utility independence and separable utility functions. Manag Sci 22:12–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rieger M, Wang M, Hens T (2015) Risk preferences around the world. Manag Sci 61:637–648

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandmo A (1970) The effect of uncertainty on saving decisions. Rev Econ Stud 37:353–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sargent T (2007) Commentary on long-run risks and financial markets. Fed Reserve Bank St Louis Rev 89:301–304

    Google Scholar 

  • Schroder M, Skiadas C (1999) Optimal consumption and portfolio selection with stochastic differential utility. J Econ Theory 89:68–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • SEC (1994) Concept and notice of hearing: safe harbor for forward-looking statements. File No. S7-29-94 Release Nos. 33-7101; 34-34831; 35-26141; 39-2324; IC-20613, Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), Washington, DC

  • Shaw W, Woodward R (2008) On why environmental and resource economists should care about non-expected utility models. Resource Energy Econ 30:66–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shogren J, Crocker T (1992) Endogenous risk and environmental policy. Tech. Rep. 92-wp91, Center for Agricultural and Rural Development (CARD) at Iowa State University

  • Skiadas C (1998) Recursive utility and preferences for information. J Econ Theory 12:293–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skiadas C (2007) Chapter 19 Dynamic portfolio choice and risk aversion, vol 15, pp 789–843

  • Slade M, Thille H (2009) Whither Hotelling: tests of the theory of exhaustible resources. Annu Rev Resource Econ 1:239–260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slimak M, Dietz T (2006) Personal values, beliefs, and ecological risk perception. Risk Anal 26:1689–1705

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith W (2007) Inspecting the mechanism exactly: a closed-form solution to a stochastic growth model. BE J Macroecon 7:1–33

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith M (2014) Fauna in decline: management risks. Science 346:819

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow R (1974) The economics of resources or the resources of economics. Am Econ Rev 64:1–14

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow R (1993) An almost practical step toward sustainability. Resour Policy 19:162–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spiro D (2014) Resource prices and planning horizons. J Econ Dyn Control 48:159–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stavins R (2011) The problem of the commons: still unsettled after 100 years. Am Econ Rev 101:81–108

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strzalecki T (2013) Temporal resolution of uncertainty and recursive models of ambiguity aversion. Econometrica 81:1039–1074

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sundaresan S (1984) Equilibrium valuation of natural resources. J Bus 57:493–518

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swanson E (2012) Risk aversion and the labor margin in dynamic equilibrium models. Am Econ Rev 102:1663–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi W (1990) Long-term environmental risks. J Risk Uncertain 3:311–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vogel D (2012) The politics of precaution: regulating health, safety, and environmental risks in Europe and the United States. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wälde K (2011) Production technologies in stochastic continuous time models. J Econ Dyn Control 35:616–622

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watkins G (1992) The Hotelling principle: Autobahn or Cul de Sac? Energy J 13:1–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wiener J, Rogers M (2002) Comparing precaution in the United States and Europe. J Risk Res 5:317–349

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young D, Ryan D (1996) Empirical testing of a risk-adjusted Hotelling model. Resources Energy Econ 18:265–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang J, Smith M (2011) Estimation of a generalized fishery model: a two-stage approach. Rev Econ Stat 93:690–699

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao G (2017) Confidence, bond risks, and equity returns. J Financ Econ 126:668–688

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Johnson Kakeu.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

None.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

We appreciate helpful comments from Valerie Thomas, Walter Pohl, Kenneth L. Judd, Stan Olijslagers, Gregory Price, Duane Cooper, Christopher Costello, Sarah Jacobson, Nicholas Flores, Jesus Fernandez-Villaverde, Yat Tin Chow, Haomin Zhou, Sung Ha Kang, Douglas Mugabe, Christos Karydas, Bruno Nkuiya, Leonidas Zelmanovitz, the seminar participants at the Stanford University SITE workshop on Asset Pricing and Computation, the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, the Georgia Tech Natural Systems Seminar, the Conference on Behavioral Aspects of Macroeconomics at Goethe University, Indiana University, University of Prince Edward Island, the Colorado University Environmental and Resource Economics Workshop, the Canadian Resource and Environment Economics Conference in London, Ontario, the World Congress of Environmental and Resource Economists, Gothenburg, Sweden, and the Atlantic Canada Economics Association Conference. All remaining errors are our own.

Appendices

Appendix

1.1 Deriving Eq. (10)

To derive Eq. (10), differentiate the maximized Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman equation (7) with respect to S to obtain

$$\begin{aligned} f_x(x(t),V(t))\frac{\partial x}{\partial S}+f_{V}(x(t),V(t))V_{S}(t)=-\frac{\partial }{\partial S}\Big (\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dV(S(t))\Big ). \end{aligned}$$
(58)

Assuming that the optimal extraction policy is represented by a smooth function \(x(t)=h(S(t))\) of the natural resource stock, the right-hand side of Eq. (58) can be computed from (8) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} -\frac{\partial }{\partial S}\Big (\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dV(S(t))\Big )= & {} -\frac{\partial }{\partial S}\left( V_{S}\Big [N(S(t)-x(t)\Big ]+\frac{1}{2}\Gamma ^{2}V_{SS}\right) \nonumber \\= & {} -\underbrace{\left( V_{SS}\Big [N(S(t))-x(t)\Big ]+\frac{1}{2}\Gamma ^{2}V_{SSS}\right) }_{ \frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dV_{S}(S(t))}\nonumber \\{} & {} -V_{S}(t)N'(S(t)+V_{S}(t)\frac{\partial h}{\partial S} \nonumber \\= & {} -\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dV_{S}(S(t))-V_{S}(t)N'(S(t)+V_{S}(t)\frac{\partial h}{\partial S} \end{aligned}$$
(59)

Plugging Eq. (59) back into Eq. (58) leads to

$$\begin{aligned} f_x(x(t),V(t))\frac{\partial h}{\partial S}+f_{V}V_{S}(t)=-\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dV_{S}(S(t))-V_{S}(t)N'(S(t))+V_{S}(t)\frac{\partial h}{\partial S}, \end{aligned}$$
(60)

which can be rewritten as

$$\begin{aligned} f_{V}(x(t),V(t))V_{S}= & {} -\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dV_{S}(S(t))-V_{S}(t)N'(S(t))\nonumber \\{} & {} +\underbrace{ \Big [V_{S}(t)-f_x(x(t),V(t))\Big ]}_{=0}\frac{\partial h}{\partial S}, \end{aligned}$$
(61)

where the last term on the right hand side vanishes since it contains the first order condition (9).

From Eq. (61), it follows that :

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dV_{S}(S(t))=\Big [-f_{V}(x(t),V(t))-N'(S(t))\Big ]V_{S}(t) \end{aligned}$$
(62)

Using the first-order Eq. (9), we may replace \(V_{S}\) by \(f_{x}(x,V)\), to obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{f_{x}(x(t),V(t))}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}df_{x}(x(t),V(t))=-f_{V}(x(t),V(t))-N'(S(t)). \end{aligned}$$
(63)

Using the Multivariate Itô Lemma, the left-hand side of Eq. (63) can be computed as:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{f_{x}(x(t),V(t))}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}df_{x}(x(t),V(t))= & {} \Big (\frac{x(t)f_{xx}(t)}{f_{x}(t)}\Big )\left[ \frac{1}{x(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dx(t)\right] \nonumber \\{} & {} +V(t)\frac{f_{xV}(t)}{f_{x}(t)}\left[ \frac{1}{V(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dV(t)\right] \nonumber \\{} & {} + \frac{1}{2}x^{2}(t)\frac{f_{xxx}(t)}{f_{x}(t)}\sigma _{x}^{2}(t)+\frac{1}{2}V^{2}(t)\frac{f_{xVV}(t)}{f_{x}(t)}\sigma _{V}^{2}(t)\nonumber \\{} & {} + x(t)V(t)\frac{f_{xxV}(t)}{f_{x}(t)}\sigma _{x}(t)\sigma _{V}(t). \end{aligned}$$
(64)

Plugging (64) back into Eq. (63) leads to

$$\begin{aligned}{} & {} \Big (\frac{x(t)f_{xx}(t)}{f_{x}(t)}\Big )\left[ \frac{1}{x(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dx(t)\right] \nonumber \\{} & {} \quad +V(t)\frac{f_{xV}(t)}{f_{x}(t)}\left[ \frac{1}{V(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dV(t)\right] \nonumber \\{} & {} \quad +\frac{1}{2}x^{2}(t)\frac{f_{xxx}(t)}{f_{x}(t)}\sigma _{x}^{2}(t)+\frac{1}{2}V^{2}(t)\frac{f_{xVV}(t)}{f_{x}(t)}\sigma _{V}^{2}(t)+x(t)V(t)\frac{f_{xxV}(t)}{f_{x}(t)}\sigma _{x}(t)\sigma _{V}(t)\nonumber \\{} & {} \quad = f_{V}(x(t),V(t))-N'(S(t)). \end{aligned}$$
(65)

It follows that

$$\begin{aligned} \underbrace{\frac{1}{x(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dx(t)}_{Expected\,pace\,of\,depletion\,of\,natural\,capital}= & {} \underbrace{\mu _{f}(t)}_{Certainty-equivalent\, pace\,at\,time\,t}\nonumber \\{} & {} +\underbrace{{\mathcal {R}}_{f}(t)}_{Risk-\,driven\,pace\, gap\,at\,time\,t}, \end{aligned}$$
(66)

where

$$\begin{aligned} \mu _{f}(t)= & {} \left[ \frac{-x(t)f_{xx}(t)}{f_{x}(t)}\right] ^{-1}\left[ f_{V}(x(t),V(t))-N'(S(t))\right. \nonumber \\{} & {} \left. +\left[ \frac{V(t)f_{xV}(t)}{f_{x}(t)}\right] \left( \frac{1}{V(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dV(t)\right) \right] , \end{aligned}$$
(67)

and

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathcal {R}}_{f}(t)= & {} \frac{1}{2}\left[ \underbrace{-\frac{x(t)^{2}(t)f_{xxx}(t)}{x(t)f_{xx}(t)}}_{weight\,on\,short{-}run\,risk}\underbrace{\sigma _{x}^{2}(t)}_{Short{-}run\,risk}\right. \nonumber \\{} & {} \left. \underbrace{- \frac{V^{2}(t)f_{xVV}(t)}{x(t)f_{xx}(t)}}_{weight\,on\,long{-}run\,risk} \underbrace{\sigma _{V}^{2}(t)}_{Long{-}run\,risk}\underbrace{- \frac{2x(t)V(t)f_{xxV}(t)}{x(t)f_{xx}(t)}}_{weight\,on\,covariance\,risk}\underbrace{\sigma _{xV}(t)}_{Covariance\,risk} \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(68)

Proof of Proposition 4.1

Proof

\((1)\,\rightrightarrows \, (2):\) Assume that at  time  t\(\frac{1}{x(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dx(t)-\mu (t)\le (\ge ) 0\)  for any  positive  semi-definite  matrix  \(\Sigma (t).\) Since \(\frac{1}{x(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dx(t)-\mu (t)\ge 0 =-\frac{1}{2}trace\Big ({\mathcal {W}}_{f}(t) \Sigma (t)\Big ),\) it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} -\frac{1}{2}trace\Big ({\mathcal {W}}_{f}(t) \Sigma _f(t)\Big ) \le (\ge )\,\, 0 \,for\,any\, \Sigma (t). \end{aligned}$$
(69)

For any given column vector \(\Psi (t)\) of size \(2\times 1\),Footnote 42 assume that the positive semi-definite matrix is of the form \(\Sigma (t)=\Psi (t)\Psi '(t).\) Since \({\mathcal {W}}_{f}(t) \Psi (t)\Psi '(t)=\Psi '(t){\mathcal {W}}_{f}(t)\Psi (t),\) then it follows from (69) that

$$\begin{aligned} -\frac{1}{2}\Psi '(t){\mathcal {W}}_{f}(t)\Psi (t)\,\le (\ge )\,\,0\,\,\,\,for\,\,any\,\,\Psi (t), \end{aligned}$$
(70)

where the row vector \(\Psi '(t)\), of size \(1\times 2,\) is the transpose of the vector \(\Psi (t).\) The inequalities shown in (70) are satisfied for any \(\Psi (t)\) if and only if the time-t matrix \({\mathcal {W}}_{f}(t)\) is positive semi-definite (negative semi-definite).

\((2)\,\rightrightarrows \,(1)\): The converse is immediate. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 4.2

Proof

\((1)\,\rightrightarrows \, (2):\) Assume that \(\left[ \frac{1}{x(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dx(t)-\mu _{f}(t)\right] - \left[ \frac{1}{{\tilde{x}}(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}d{\tilde{x}}(t)-\mu _{g}(t)\right] \le 0\) for any positive semi-definite matrix \(\Sigma (t).\)

Since \(\left[ \frac{1}{x(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dx(t)-\mu _{f}(t)\right] - \left[ \frac{1}{{\tilde{x}}(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}d{\tilde{x}}(t)-\mu _{g}(t)\right] =-\frac{1}{2}trace\Big \{\left[ {\mathcal {W}}_{f}(t)-{\mathcal {W}}_{g}(t)\right] \Sigma (t)\Big \},\) it follows that at time t

$$\begin{aligned} -\frac{1}{2}trace\Big \{\left[ {\mathcal {W}}_{f}(t)-{\mathcal {W}}_{g}(t)\right] \Sigma (t)\Big \}\le \,0\,\,for\,any\,\,\Sigma (t). \end{aligned}$$
(71)

For any column vector \(\Psi (t)\) of size \(2\times 1\), choosing \(\Sigma (t)\) of the form \(\Psi (t)\Psi '(t)\) and pursuing to (71) leads to

$$\begin{aligned} -\frac{1}{2}\Psi '(t)\left[ {\mathcal {W}}_{f}(t)-{\mathcal {W}}_{g}(t)\right] \Psi (t)\le \,0\,\,for\,\,any\,\,\Psi (t), \end{aligned}$$
(72)

where the row vector \(\Psi '(t)\), of size \(1\times 2,\) is the transpose of the vector \(\Psi (t).\)

The inequality (72)   holds for any vector \(\Psi (t)\) if and only if the time-t symmetric matrix \({\mathcal {W}}_{f}(t)-{\mathcal {W}}_{g}(t)\) is positive semi-definite. From proposition 4.1, it is readily seen that \({\mathcal {W}}_{f}(t)\) and \({\mathcal {W}}_{g}(t)\) are positive semi-definite.

\((2)\,\rightrightarrows \, (1):\) The converse is immediate. \(\square\)

Derivation of the Closed Form Solution for a Hotelling’s Homogeneous Resource Depletion Problem with Schroder and Skiadas (1999) Recursive Utility

To find a closed-form solution to the Bellman equation, we conjecture that the value function is of the form

$$\begin{aligned} V(t)=(\Phi S(t))^{\gamma (1+\alpha )}>0, \end{aligned}$$
(73)

for some positive parameter \(\Phi\) to be determined. Substituting the educated guess (73) into (49), it turns out that the optimal extraction policy is given by

$$\begin{aligned} x(t)=\left( \gamma ^{\frac{1}{\gamma -1}}\Phi ^{\frac{\gamma }{\gamma -1}}\right) S(t). \end{aligned}$$
(74)

Substituting the educated guess (73) into the maximized Bellman equation (50) leads to

$$\begin{aligned}{} & {} (1+\alpha ) S^{\gamma \alpha +1}\Big [\frac{ \left( \left( \gamma ^{\frac{1}{\gamma -1}}\Phi ^{\frac{\gamma }{\gamma -1}}\right) S\right) ^{\gamma } }{\gamma }(\Phi S)^{\gamma \alpha }-\beta \Phi ^{\gamma (1+ \alpha )}\Big ] \nonumber \\{} & {} \quad - \left[ \gamma ^{\gamma -1}\Phi ^{\frac{\gamma }{\gamma -1}}\right] S \gamma (1+\alpha )\Phi \Phi ^{\gamma (1+\alpha )-1}S^{\gamma (1+\alpha )-1}\nonumber \\{} & {} \quad + \frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}\gamma (1+\alpha ) (\gamma (1+\alpha )-1)\Phi ^2\Phi ^{\gamma (1+\alpha )}S^{\gamma (1+ \alpha )-2}S^{2} \nonumber \\{} & {} \quad =0. \end{aligned}$$
(75)

It follows that

$$\begin{aligned} (1+\alpha )(\Phi S)^{\gamma (1+ \alpha )} \Big [\gamma ^{\gamma -1}\Phi ^{\frac{\gamma }{\gamma -1}}\left( \frac{1}{\gamma }-\gamma \right) -\beta +\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}\gamma (\gamma (\alpha +1)-1) \Big ]=0, \end{aligned}$$
(76)

which gives

$$\begin{aligned} \Phi =\left[ \frac{ \beta + \frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}\gamma ( 1- \gamma (\alpha +1)) }{\left( \frac{ 1}{\gamma } -\gamma \right) \gamma ^{\gamma -1}}\right] ^{\frac{\gamma -1}{\gamma } }. \end{aligned}$$
(77)

Substituting Eqs. (73) and (74) into Eq. (48), the expected rate of change of the shadow price of the resource stock, assuming \(\gamma >0,\) is obtained as:

$$\begin{aligned} \underbrace{\frac{1}{V_{S}(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_tdV_{S}(t)}_{Expected\,rate\,of\,change\,of\,the\,resource\,shadow\,price}= & {} \underbrace{ \underbrace{\beta }_{Discount\, rate}}_{>0}+ \underbrace{\underbrace{(1-\gamma )\sigma ^{2}}_{Premium\,for\,Short{-}Run\,\, risk}}_{>0}\nonumber \\{} & {} - \underbrace{ \underbrace{ \alpha \left[ \gamma ^{\frac{1}{\gamma -1}}\Phi ^{\frac{\gamma }{\gamma -1}}+\gamma \sigma ^{2}+\beta \right] }_{Premium\,\, for\,\,temporal\,\, resolution \,\, of\,uncertainty}}_{\lesseqqgtr \,0}, \end{aligned}$$
(78)

where the expression of \(\Phi\) is given by Eq. (77).

1.1 The Transversality Condition

Pertaining to (53) and (41), along the optimal path, the stochastic dynamic of the resource stock takes the form

$$\begin{aligned} dS(t)=-\gamma ^{\frac{1}{\gamma -1}}\Phi ^{\frac{\gamma }{\gamma -1}}S(t)dt+\sigma S(t)dB(t),\,\,S_{0}>0\,\,given. \end{aligned}$$
(79)

Therefore

$$\begin{aligned} S(t)=S_{0}\,e^{\left( - |\gamma |^{\frac{1}{\gamma -1}}\Phi ^{\frac{\gamma }{\gamma -1}}-\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}\right) t+\sigma B(t)}\,>0. \end{aligned}$$
(80)

Since \(e^{-\nu t} E\left( |V(t)|\right) = e^{-\nu t} E\Big [ (\Phi S(t))^{\gamma (1+\alpha )} \Big ] =e^{-\nu t}\Phi ^{\gamma (1+\alpha )} E\Big [ S(t)^{\gamma (1+\alpha )} \Big ]\), it follows, using Eq. (80), that

$$\begin{aligned} e^{-\nu t} E\left( |V(t)|\right)= & {} \Phi ^{\gamma (1+\alpha )} S_{0}^{\gamma (1+\alpha )}\,e^{\left( -\nu +\gamma (1+\alpha )\left[ - |\gamma |^{\frac{1}{\gamma -1}}\Phi ^{\frac{\gamma }{\gamma -1}} -\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}\right] \right) t}\,\,E\left( e^{ \gamma (1+\alpha )\sigma B(t)}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(81)

Noting that the term \(E\left( e^{ \gamma (1+\alpha )\sigma B(t)}\right)\) is the expected value of a Geometric Brownian Motion, it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} e^{-\nu t}E\left( |V(S(t)|\right)= & {} \Phi ^{\gamma (1+\alpha )} S_{0}^{\gamma (1+\alpha )}\,e^{\left( -\nu +\gamma (1+\alpha )\left[ - |\gamma |^{\frac{1}{\gamma -1}}\Phi ^{\frac{\gamma }{\gamma -1}} -\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}\right] + \frac{1}{2}(\gamma (1+\alpha )\sigma )^{2}\right) t}. \end{aligned}$$
(82)

Then the transversality condition (see footnote 32) is verified if the exponent in (82) is negative; that is

$$\begin{aligned} \nu >\gamma (1+\alpha )\left[ - |\gamma |^{\frac{1}{\gamma -1}}\Phi ^{\frac{\gamma }{\gamma -1}} -\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}\right] + \frac{1}{2}(\gamma (1+\alpha )\sigma )^{2}, \end{aligned}$$
(83)

or

$$\begin{aligned} \nu >\gamma (1+\alpha )\left[ - \left[ \frac{ \beta + \frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}\gamma (\gamma (\alpha +1)-1) }{\gamma - \frac{ 1}{\gamma } }\right] -\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}\right] + \frac{1}{2}(\gamma (1+\alpha )\sigma )^{2}, \end{aligned}$$
(84)

by replacing the term \(|\gamma |^{\frac{1}{\gamma -1}}\Phi ^{\frac{\gamma }{\gamma -1}}\) by its expression obtained from Eq. (77).

Computational Simulation for the Stationary Optimal Policy with a Schroder and Skiadas (1999) Recursive Utility and a Renewable Resource Growing Nonlinearly

For the computational simulation of the stationary optimal policy with Schroder and Skiadas (1999) recursive utility and a renewable resource growing nonlinearly, we have developed an algorithm that combines the Crank and Nicolson (1974) scheme and the numerical techniques by Achdou et al. (2021). The numerical algorithm computes the value function at each step n iteratively as the solution to a system of linear equations, \(L*V^{n+1}=U*V^{n}\), where L and U are large tridiagonal matrices.Footnote 43

Fig. 3
figure 3

a Stationary Value Function, b Stationary Extraction Policy. We consider the recursive utility \(f(x,V)=(1+\alpha )\Big [\frac{x^{\gamma }}{\gamma }V^{\frac{\alpha }{1+\alpha }}-\beta V\Big ]\), with preference parameters \(\beta =3\%\), \(\alpha =-0.037\), \(\gamma =0.5\), variance of volatility shocks \(\Gamma =2\), and nonlinear natural resource growth function \(N(S)=r*S^p\), with \(r=0.2\) and \(p=0.5\)

The numerical simulations, shown in Fig. 3, suggest that the value function V(S) of the stationary resource problem is concave, and the extraction policy x(S) depends nonlinearly upon the stock.

We use MATLAB to perform the necessary computations. Our numerical algorithm converges after 3768 iterations, as illustrated in Fig. 4.Footnote 44

Fig. 4
figure 4

A threshold of \(10^{-6}\) verifies the convergence to the stationary value function

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kakeu, J. Concerns for Long-Run Risks and Natural Resource Policy. Environ Resource Econ 84, 1051–1093 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-022-00748-0

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-022-00748-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation