Skip to main content
Log in

A Discontinuity Model of Technological Change: Catastrophe Theory and Network Structure

  • Published:
Computational Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Discontinuities as a crucial aspect of economic systems have been discussed both verbally—particularly in institutionality theory—and formally, chiefly using catastrophe theory. Catastrophe theory has, however, been criticized heavily for lacking micro-foundations and has mainly fallen out of use in economics and social sciences. The present paper proposes a simple catastrophe theory model of technological change with network externalities and reevaluates the value of such a model by adding an agent-based micro layer. To this end an agent-based variant of the model is proposed and investigated specifically with regard to the network structure among the agents. While the macro level of the model produces a classical cusp catastrophe—a result that is preserved in the agent-based form—it is found that the behavior of the model changes locally depending on the network structure, especially if networks with features that resemble social networks (low diameter, high clustering, power law distributed node degree) are considered. While the present work investigates merely an aspect out of a large possibility space, it encourages further research using agent-based catastrophe theory models especially of economic aspects to which catastrophe theory has previously successfully been applied; aspects such as technological and institutional change, economic crises, or industry structure.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In game theory models, rational anticipation of the response of the second mover may play a role but it is questionable if that would be preserved under stochastic perturbation and other modifications.

  2. Note that this equation has a canonic functional for equations for technological change with network externalities. It corresponds to s-shape equations (or strong s-property) in Arthur et al. (1983[1982], 1987).

  3. By substituting

    $$\begin{aligned} a=-\frac{1}{3}z^2 \end{aligned}$$

    and

    $$\begin{aligned} b=-\frac{2z^3}{27}+z\beta . \end{aligned}$$
  4. Dunbar (1993) for instance proposed a number of around 300. There are some models that nevertheless propose using Barabási-Albert networks as a model of social networks, e.g. Barash et al. (2012)—the argument of networks among social groups (as opposed to within social groups) may be relevant to this discussion.

  5. This has been suggested directly in some models (Dahui et al. 2006; Stephen and Toubia 2009, but since both the size of firms (profits, capital, number of employees) and the degrees of the internet (but also the sizes of urban centers and many other quantities related to network technologies in one way or another) are known to be power law distributed (Newman 2005; Delli Gatti et al. 2005, this is generally a plausible assumption related to other stylized facts.

  6. The diameter of a network is the longest distance (shortest path) between two nodes in the network. A small diameter compared to the size of the network (number of nodes) this means that the network are relatively well-connected, more specifically having Watts and Strogatz’ small world property (Watts and Strogatz 1998) (or having a huge number of links compared to the number of nodes, thus being a complete or almost complete network as this would also lead to a small diameter).

  7. These two properties (and the conjunction of these two properties) in social networks has received particular attention in the small-world network literature (Watts and Strogatz 1998); for an extensive overview, see Schnettler (2009).

  8. The concept of triadic closure is, however, older. It was first applied in sociology and made popular in network theory by Granovetter (1973).

  9. The betweenness centrailty of a node i is the share of shortest path \(sp_{j,k}\) in the network between any two nodes (j and k) of which it is part (denoted \(sp_{j,k}(i)\))

    $$\begin{aligned} bc(i)=\sum _{j\ne k\ne i} \frac{sp_{j,k}(i)}{sp_{j,k}}. \end{aligned}$$
  10. In fact, the distributions of the node’s betweenness centrality seem to decay according to a power law for the preferential attachment network and the preferential attachment network with triadic closure, but with different tail slopes.

  11. Note that this module uses a breadth-first search algorithm to obtain a single shortest path between any two nodes. As in regular grid networks there are always many equally short paths, one is selected randomly, therefore the computed betweenness centralities differ slighly between the nodes; the correct result would be a constant and equal value for all nodes.

  12. Further, for the network 7, the number of links is such that the network is directly comparable to a Barabási-Albert preferential attachment network of the same size (Fig. 9).

  13. However, some promising approaches exist; these include urn schemes (Arthur et al. 1987; Buendía 2013) and network externality based models.

References

  • Arthur, W. B. (1989). Competing technologies, increasing returns, and lock-in by historical events. Economic Journal, 99(394), 116–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arthur, W. B., Ermoliev, Y. M., & Kaniovski, Y. M. (1983 [1982]). A generalized urn problem and its applications. Cybernetics, 19, 61–71. (translated from Russian [Kibernetica 1:49–56])

  • Arthur, W. B., Ermoliev, Y. M., & Kaniovski, Y. M. (1987). Path dependent processes and the emergence of macro-structure. European Journal of Operational Research, 30, 294–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barabási, A. L., & Albert, R. (1999). Emergence of scaling in random networks. Science, 286(5439), 509–512. doi:10.1126/science.286.5439.509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barash, V., Cameron, C., & Macy, M. (2012). Critical phenomena in complex contagions. Social Networks, 34(4), 451–461. doi:10.1016/j.socnet.2012.02.003.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bass, F. M. (1969). A new product growth for model consumer durables. Management Science, 15(5), 215–227. doi:10.1287/mnsc.15.5.215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buendía, F. (2013). Self-organizing market structures, system dynamics, and urn theory. Complexity, 18(4), 28–40. doi:10.1002/cplx.21442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahui, W., Li, Z., & Zengru, D. (2006). Bipartite producer-consumer networks and the size distribution of firms. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 363(2), 359–366. doi:10.1016/j.physa.2005.08.006.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • David, P. A. (1985). Clio and the economics of QWERTY. American Economic Review, 75(2), 332–337.

    Google Scholar 

  • David, P. A. (1992). Heroes, herds and hysteresis in technological history: Thomas Edison and the battle of the systems reconsidered. Industrial and Corporate Change, 1(1), 129–180. doi:10.1093/icc/1.1.129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • David, P. A., & Bunn, J. A. (1988). The economics of gateway technologies and network evolution: Lessons from electricity supply history. Information Economics and Policy, 3(2), 165–202. doi:10.1016/0167-6245(88)90024-8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • David, P. A., & Steinmueller, W. (1994). Economics of compatibility standards and competition in telecommunication networks. Information Economics and Policy, 6(3–4), 217–241. doi:10.1016/0167-6245(94)90003-5.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delli Gatti, D., Di Guilmi, C., Gaffeo, E., Giulioni, G., Gallegati, M., & Palestrini, A. (2005). A new approach to business fluctuations: heterogeneous interacting agents, scaling laws and financial fragility. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 56(4), 489–512. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2003.10.012. Festschrift in honor of Richard H. Day.

  • Dolfsma, W., & Leydesdorff, L. (2009). Lock-in and break-out from technological trajectories: Modeling and policy implications. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 76(7), 932–941. doi:10.1016/j.techfore.2009.02.004.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G. (1982). Technological paradigms and technological trajectories: A suggested interpretation of the determinants and directions of technical change. Research Policy, 11(3), 147–162. doi:10.1016/0048-7333(82)90016-6.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dou, W., & Ghose, S. (2006). A dynamic nonlinear model of online retail competition using cusp catastrophe theory. Journal of Business Research, 59(7), 838–848. doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2006.02.003.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunbar, R. I. M. (1993). Coevolution of neocortical size, group size and language in humans. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 16(04), 681–694. doi:10.1017/S0140525X00032325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, C., & Perez, C. (1988). Structural crisis of adjustment, business cycles and investment behaviour. In G. Dosi, C. Freeman, R. Nelson, G. Silverberg, & L. Soete (Eds.), Technological change and economic theory (pp. 38–66). London: Pinter Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter, M. S. (1973). The strength of weak ties. American Journal of Sociology, 78(6), 1360–1380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gräbner, C., & Kapeller, J. (2016). The micro-macro link in heterodox economics. In L. Chester, C. D’Ippoliti, & T.-H. Jo (Eds.), The handbook of heterodox economics. Oxon: Routledge.

  • Gräbner, C., Heinrich, T., & Kudic, M. (2016). Structuration processes in complex dynamic systems an overview and reassessment. MPRA Paper 69095. http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/69095/.

  • Heinrich, T. (2014). Standard wars, tied standards, and network externality induced path dependence in the ICT sector. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 81, 309–320. doi:10.1016/j.techfore.2013.04.015.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herbig, P. A. (1991). A cusp catastrophe model of the adoption of an industrial innovation. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 8(2), 127–137. doi:10.1016/0737-6782(91)90006-K.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz, M. L., & Shapiro, C. (1985). Network externalities, competition and compatibility. American Economic Review, 75(3), 424–440.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lange, R., Mcdade, S. R., & Oliva, T. A. (2004). The estimation of a cusp model to describe the adoption of Word for Windows. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 21(1), 15–32. doi:10.1111/j.0737-6782.2004.00051.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myrdal, G. (1974). What is development? Journal of Economic Issues, 8(4), 729–736.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R. (1968). A ”diffusion model” of international productivity differences in manufacturing industry. American Economic Review, 58, 1219–1248.

    Google Scholar 

  • Newman, M. E. J. (2005). Power laws, Pareto distributions and Zipf’s law. Contemporary Physics, 46(5), 323–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nowak, M. A. (2006). Evolutionary dynamics: Exploring the equations of life. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosser, J. B. (2000). From catastrophe to chaos: A general theory of economic discontinuities: Mathematics microeconomics and finance. New York: Springer.

  • Rosser, J. B. (2007). The rise and fall of catastrophe theory applications in economics: Was the baby thrown out with the bathwater? Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 31(10), 3255–3280. doi:10.1016/j.jedc.2006.09.013.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saunders, P. T. (1980). An introduction to catastrophe theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schnettler, S. (2009). A structured overview of 50 years of small-world research. Social Networks, 31(3), 165–178. doi:10.1016/j.socnet.2008.12.004.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sewell, M. J. (1977). Elementary catastrophe theory. In F. Branin Jr. & K. Huseyin (Eds.), Problem analyses in science and engineering (pp. 391–426). New York: Academic Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Silverberg, G., & Lehnert, D. (1993). Long waves and ‘evolutionary chaos’ in a simple Schumpeterian model of embodied technical change. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 4(9), 9–37. doi:10.1016/0954-349X(93)90003-3.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silverberg, G., & Verspagen, B. (2005). A percolation model of innovation in complex technology spaces. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 29(1—-2), 225–244. doi:10.1016/j.jedc.2003.05.005.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stephen, A. T., & Toubia, O. (2009). Explaining the power-law degree distribution in a social commerce network. Social Networks, 31(4), 262–270. doi:10.1016/j.socnet.2009.07.002.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thom, R. (1975). Structural stability and morphogenesis: an outline of a general theory of models. The Advanced Book Program, W. A: Benjamin, Reading, MA, USA, translated from French by D.H. Fowler.

  • Vázquez, A. (2003). Growing network with local rules: Preferential attachment, clustering hierarchy, and degree correlations. Physical Review E, 67(056), 104. doi:10.1103/PhysRevE.67.056104.

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T. B. (1898). Why is economics not an evolutionary science? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 12(4), 373–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T. B. (2008 [1899]). Theory of the Leisure Class. Project Gutenberg, http://www.gutenberg.org/ebooks/833

  • Watts, D. J., & Strogatz, S. H. (1998). Collective dynamics of ’small-world’ networks. Nature, 393(6684), 440–442. doi:10.1038/30918.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Windrum, P. (2003). Unlocking a lock-in: Towards a model of technological succession. In P. P. Saviotti (Ed.), Applied evolutionary economics new empirical methods and simulation techniques. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodcock, A., & Davis, M. (1978). Catastrophe theory: A revolutionary new way of understanding how things change. New York: Dutton.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author would like to thank an anonymous reviewer as well as the discussants of the 2014 EAEPE conference for many helpful comments. The usual disclaimers apply.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Torsten Heinrich.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

There are no conflicts of interest.

Ethical approval

The research presented in this paper is in compliance with accepted ethical standards for good science.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Heinrich, T. A Discontinuity Model of Technological Change: Catastrophe Theory and Network Structure. Comput Econ 51, 407–425 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10614-016-9609-9

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10614-016-9609-9

Keywords

Navigation