Skip to main content
Log in

Banking competition and welfare

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Annals of Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We develop a simple general equilibrium model in which investment in a risky technology is subject to moral hazard and banks can extract market power rents. We show that more bank competition results in lower economy-wide risk, higher social welfare, lower bank capital ratios, more efficient production plans and Pareto-ranked real allocations. Perfect competition supports a second best allocation and optimal levels of bank risk and capitalization. These results are at variance with those obtained by a large literature that has studied a similar environment in partial equilibrium, they are empirically relevant, and carry significant implications for policy guidance.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Freixas and Ma (2015) show that competition affects the level of risk depending on banks’ leverage, where they assume the cost of capital higher than the cost of debt. Regarding the welfare dimension, Maudos and de Guevara (2007) show empirically that the welfare gains associated with a reduction of market power in the banking sector are greater than the loss of bank cost efficiency.

  2. For detailed surveys of these literatures, see Gorton and Winton (2003) and Freixas and Rochet (2008).

  3. Boyd et al. (2002) also show that some of the standard implications of partial equilibrium modeling concerning the risk effects of deposit insurance may not necessarily hold in general equilibrium.

  4. See Krasa and Villamil (1992) for a model of a bank with imperfect diversification and an optimal bank

    size.

  5. The rationale behind changes in the optimal values of risk and specialization to changes in parameters are straightforward: The optimal level of risk declines (\(p^{O}\) increases) in both W and k, as well as in X, and increases in the (utility) cost of choosing p-projects, parameterized by \(\alpha \). The optimal fraction of entrepreneurs increases in k and declines in W.

  6. In our context, we do not view the case \(R>R^{*}\) as economically relevant, since the existence of coalitions of depositors extracting market power rents from banks is unrealistic.

References

  • Akins, B., Li, L., Ng, J., Rusticus, T.O.: Bank competition and financial stability: evidence from the financial crisis. J Financ Quant Anal 51(01), 1–28 (2016)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen, F., Gale, D.: Comparing Financial Systems. MIT Press, Cambridge (2000)

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, F., Gale, D.: Competition and financial stability. J Money Credit Bank 36(2), 453–480 (2004a)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen, F., Gale, D.: Financial intermediaries and markets. Econometrica 72(4), 1023–1061 (2004b)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barth, J.R., Caprio Jr., G., Levine, R.: Bank supervision and regulation: what works best? J Financ Intermed 13(2), 205–248 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Levine, R.: Bank concentration, competition, and crises: first results. J Bank Finance 30, 1581–1603 (2006a)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Levine, R.: Bank concentration and fragility: impact and mechanics. In: Stulz, R., Carey, M. (eds.) The Risks of Financial Institutions. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge (2006b)

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger, A.N., Klapper, L.F., Turk-Ariss, R.: Bank competition and financial stability. J Financ Serv Res 35(2), 99–118 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Booth, A.W., Thakor, A.V.: Financial system architecture. Rev Financ Stud 10(3), 693–733 (1997)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, J.H., De Nicolò, G., Jalal, A.M.: Bank Competition, Risk, and Asset Allocations, IMF Working Paper 09/143, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC (2009a)

  • Boyd, J.H., De Nicolò, G., Loukoianova, E.:Banking crises and crisis dating: theory and evidence. IMF Working Papers 1–50 (2009b)

  • Boyd, J.H., De Nicolò, G., Jalal, A.M.: Bank Risk and Competition: New Theory and New Evidence, IMF Working Paper # 06/297, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC (2006)

  • Boyd, J.H., Chung, C., Bruce, D.S.: Deposit insurance: a reconsideration. J Monet Econ 49, 1235–1260 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, J.H., De Nicolò, G., Smith, B.D.: Crises in competitive versus monopolistic banking systems. J Money Credit Bank 36(3), 487–506 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, J.H., De Nicolò, G.: The theory of bank risk taking and competition revisited. J Finance 60(3), 1329–1343 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, J.H., Prescott, E.: Financial intermediary coalitions. J Econ Theory 38, 211–232 (1986)

    Google Scholar 

  • De Nicolò, G., Loukoianova, E.: Bank ownership, market structure and risk, IMF Working Paper, 07/215, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC (2007)

  • De Nicolò, G., Turk Ariss, R.: Bank Market power Rents and Risk: Theory and Measurement, manuscript and forthcoming. IMF Working Paper (2009)

  • Diamond, D., Dybvig, P.: Bank runs, liquidity and deposit insurance. J Polit Econ 91, 401–419 (1983)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freixas, X., Ma, K.: Banking Competition and Stability: The Role of Leverage, Barcelona GSE W.P. n. 781 (2015)

  • Freixas, X., Rochet, J.-C.: Microeconomics of Banking. MIT Press, Cambridge (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gorton, G., Winton, A.: Financial intermediation, chapter 8. In: Constantinides, G.M., Harris, M., Stulz, R. (eds.) Handbook of the Economics of Finance. Helsevier, Amsterdam (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hellmann, T., Murdock, K., Stiglitz, J.: Liberalization, moral hazard in banking, and prudential regulation: are capital requirements enough? Am Econ Rev 90(1), 147–165 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B., Tirole, J.: Financial intermediation, loanable funds, and the real sector. Q J Econ CXII 3, 663–691 (1997)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jayaratne, J., Strahan, P.: Entry restrictions, industry evolution, and dynamic efficiency: evidence from commercial banking. J Law Econ 41, 239–275 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keeley, M.: Deposit insurance, risk and market power in banking. Am Econ Rev 80, 1183–1200 (1990)

    Google Scholar 

  • Krasa, S., Villamil, A.: A theory of optimal bank size. Oxf Econ Pap 44(1992), 38–63 (1992)

    Google Scholar 

  • Martinez-Miera, D., Repullo, R.: Does competition reduce the risk of bank failure? Rev Financ Stud 23(10), 3638–3664 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matutes, C., Vives, X.: Competition for deposits, fragility, and insurance. J Financ Intermed 5, 186–216 (1996)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maudos, J., de Guevara, J.F.: The cost of market power in banking: social welfare loss vs. cost inefficiency. J Bank Finance 31(7), 2103–2125 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nicola, C., Michele, G.: Banking market structure, financial dependence and growth: international evidence from industry data. J Finance 56(2), 617–648 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nicola, C., Strahan, P.: Finance as a barrier to entry: bank competition and industry structure in local U.S. markets. J Finance 61(1), 437–661 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Repullo, R.: Capital requirements, market power, and risk-taking in banking. J Financ Intermed 13, 156–182 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tito, C., Levi-Yeyati, E.: Financial opening, deposit insurance, and risk in a model of banking competition. Eur Econ Rev 46, 693–733 (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Zigraiova, D., Havranek, T.: Bank competition and financial stability: much ado about nothing. J Econ Surv 30(5), 944–981 (2016)

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marcella Lucchetta.

Appendix

Appendix

Proposition 1

In the moral hazard economy with banks and depositors an equilibrium with intermediation exists and it is unique for every \(R\in (\frac{Xk}{2W},X]\).

Proof

Rearranging (10) and rewriting (11), we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} I_1 (q)\equiv & {} I=\frac{2RWq-Xk}{X-R}; \end{aligned}$$
(41)

and

$$\begin{aligned} I_2 (q)\equiv I=\frac{W}{2}(1-q^{2}). \end{aligned}$$
(42)

An equilibrium is a value of \(q\in (0,1)\) that satisfies (41) and (42). Observe that \(I_2 (0)=\frac{W}{2}>-\frac{Xk}{X-R}=I_1 (0),\) while \(I_2 (1)=0<\frac{2RW-Xk}{X-R}=I_1 (1)\) if \(R\ge \frac{Xk}{2W}\), which is necessary for \(I_1 \) to be non-negative for every value of \(q\in (0,1)\), otherwise no equilibrium would exist. Let \(F(q)\equiv I_2 (q)-I_1 (q)=\frac{W}{2}(1-q^{2})-\frac{2RWq-Xk}{X-R}\). Clearly, \({F}'(q)<0\) holds. Therefore, there exists a unique value of \(q^{*}\in (0,1)\) such that \(F(q^{*})=0\). \(I^{*}\) is found using either (41) or (42). Using (8), \(p^{*}=\alpha ^{-1}\left[ {(X-R)I^{*}+Xk} \right] \). \(\square \)

Proposition 2

In the moral hazard economy with banks and depositors:

$$\begin{aligned} I_R^*>0, \quad \hat{{q}}_R^*<0, \quad p_R^*>0, \quad K_R^*<0 ~{ and}~ p_k^*>0. \end{aligned}$$

Proof

Differentiating totally (10) and (11) with respect to I, q, R and k, we get:

$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle \frac{X-R}{2}dI-RWdq=qWdR-\frac{X}{2}dk; \end{aligned}$$
(43)
$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle dI+qWdq=0. \end{aligned}$$
(44)

The determinant of the system (43)–(44) is \(\Delta =\frac{X-R}{2}qW+RW>0\).

Setting \(dk=0\), by Cramer’s rule,

$$\begin{aligned} I_R =\frac{dI}{dR}=\frac{1}{\Delta }(qW)^{2}>0, \end{aligned}$$
(45)

and

$$\begin{aligned} q_R \equiv \frac{dq}{dR}=-\frac{1}{\Delta }qW<0. \end{aligned}$$
(46)

Substituting (41) in (8), we get:

$$\begin{aligned} p=\frac{2RWq}{\alpha } \end{aligned}$$
(47)

Differentiating (47) with respect to R, we get:

$$\begin{aligned} p_R \equiv \frac{dp}{dR}=\frac{2Wq}{\alpha }+\frac{2RW}{\alpha }q_R =\frac{2Wq}{\alpha }\left( {1-\frac{RW}{\Delta }} \right) >0, \end{aligned}$$
(48)

where the second equality was obtained using (46), and the last inequality derives from \(\Delta >RW\).

Finally, by (45) and (46)

$$\begin{aligned} K_R =\frac{k}{(I+qk)^{2}}(q_R I-qI_R )<0 \end{aligned}$$
(49)

Setting \(dR=0\) and following the same procedure above, we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} q_k \equiv \frac{dq}{dk}=\frac{X}{2\Delta }>0. \end{aligned}$$
(50)

Therefore,

$$\begin{aligned} p_k \equiv \frac{dp}{dk}=\frac{2RW}{\alpha }q_k >0 \end{aligned}$$
(51)

\(\square \)

Proposition 3

In the no-moral hazard economy with banks and depositors an equilibrium with intermediation exists and it is unique for every \(R\in (\frac{X^{2}k^{2}}{2\alpha W},\frac{X^{2}(W+2k)^{2}}{4\alpha W})\).

Proof

Rearranging (17) and (18), we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} q_1 (I)\equiv q=\frac{X^{2}(I+k)^{2}}{2\alpha RW}-\frac{I}{W}; \end{aligned}$$
(52)

and

$$\begin{aligned} q_2 (I)\equiv q=\sqrt{1-\frac{2I}{W}}. \end{aligned}$$
(53)

An equilibrium is a value of \(I\in (0,\frac{W}{2}]\) that satisfies (41) and (42).

Observe that \(q_1 (0)=\frac{X^{2}k^{2}}{2\alpha RW}\), \(q_1 (I)\) is strictly concave in I and strictly decreasing for all \(I>I_{\max } \), where \(I>I_{\max } \) is the maximum of \(q_1 (I)\). Thus, there exists a value \(\hat{{I}}>I_{\max } \) such that \(q_1 (\hat{{I}})=0\). On the other hand, \(q_2 (0)=1\), \(q_2 (I)\) is strictly decreasing, and \(q_2 (\frac{W}{2})=0\).

Thus, a unique intersection of \(q_1 (I)\) and \(q_2 (I)\)—that is, a value of \(I\in (0,\frac{W}{2}]\) that satisfies (41) and (42)—will occur for some \(I\in (0,\frac{W}{2}]\) only if \(q_2 (0)=1\ge \frac{X^{2}k^{2}}{2\alpha RW}=q_1 (0)\) (51), and \(q_2 (\frac{W}{2})=0\le \frac{X^{2}(W+2k)^{2}}{8\alpha RW}-\frac{1}{2}=q_1 (\frac{W}{2})\) (A12). Inequality (51) implies \(R\ge \frac{X^{2}k^{2}}{2\alpha W}\), while inequality (A12) implies \(R\le \frac{X^{2}(W+2k)^{2}}{4\alpha W}\). Thus, for every \(R\in (\frac{X^{2}k^{2}}{2\alpha W},\frac{X^{2}(W+2k)^{2}}{4\alpha W})\), an equilibrium exists and it is unique. Using (16), \(p^{*}=\alpha ^{-1}[X(I^{*}+k)]\). \(\square \)

Proposition 4

In the no-moral hazard economy with banks and depositors:

$$\begin{aligned} I_R^*>0, \quad \hat{{q}}_R^*<0, \quad p_R^*>0, \quad K_R^*<0 ~{ and}~p_k^*>0. \end{aligned}$$

Proof

Differentiating totally (17) and (18) with respect to I, q, R and k, we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle \left( {\frac{X^{2}(I+k)}{\alpha }-R} \right) dI-RWdq=(qW+I)dR-\frac{X^{2}(I+k)}{\alpha }dk; \end{aligned}$$
(54)
$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle dI+qWdq=0. \end{aligned}$$
(55)

The determinant of the system (54)–(55) is \(\Delta =\frac{X^{2}(I+k)}{\alpha }qW+RW(1-q)>0\).

Setting \(dk=0\), by Cramer’s rule,

$$\begin{aligned} I_R =\frac{dI}{dR}=\frac{1}{\Delta }(qW+I)qW>0, \end{aligned}$$
(56)

and

$$\begin{aligned} q_R \equiv \frac{dq}{dR}=-\frac{1}{\Delta }(qW+I)<0. \end{aligned}$$
(57)

Differentiating (16) with respect to R, we get:

$$\begin{aligned} p_R \equiv \frac{dp}{dR}=\frac{XI}{\alpha }I_R >0, \end{aligned}$$
(58)

where we have used (56).

Finally, by (56) and (57)

$$\begin{aligned} K_R =\frac{k}{(I+qk)^{2}}(q_R I-qI_R )<0 \end{aligned}$$
(59)

Setting \(dR=0\), and following the same procedure above, we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} I_k =\frac{dI}{dk}=-\frac{1}{\Delta }qW\frac{X^{2}(I+k)}{\alpha }<0, \end{aligned}$$
(60)

Hence,

$$\begin{aligned} p_R \equiv \frac{dp}{dR}=\frac{X}{\alpha }(I_k +1)=\frac{X}{\alpha }\left( 1-\frac{qWX^{2}(I+k)\alpha ^{-1}}{qWX^{2}(I+k)\alpha ^{-1}+RW(1-q)}\right) >0,\qquad \end{aligned}$$
(61)

where we have used (60) and \(\Delta \). \(\square \)

Proposition 5

In the moral hazard economy with banks and depositors, there is no equilibrium with intermediation that supports the Pareto optimal allocation.

Proof

Inserting (11) in (8), replacing (pq) with \((p^{O},q^{O})\) in (8) and (10), and solving for R in (8) and (10) respectively, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} R_1\equiv & {} R=X+\frac{2Xk-2\alpha p^{O}}{W(1-q^{O 2})} \end{aligned}$$
(62)
$$\begin{aligned} R_2\equiv & {} R=\frac{XW(1-q^{O 2})+2Xk}{W(1-q^{O 2})+4q^{O}W} \end{aligned}$$
(63)

Using (25) in (62) and (63) yields \(R_1 =0\ne \frac{4XW}{4W-2k+20W\sqrt{\frac{2k+W}{5W}}}=R_2 \).

Thus, there does not exist a value of which yields an equilibrium with \((p,q)=(p^{O},q^{O})\). Thus, there is no equilibrium that supports the Pareto optimal allocation. \(\square \)

Proposition 6

In the moral hazard economy with banks and depositors, \(R^{*}\) is an equilibrium with intermediation that supports the second best allocation.

Proof

A solution \(R^{*}\) to problem (26) subject to (27) exists, since the continuous function V(.) in (26) is maximized over the compact set (27). Since function V(.) is strictly concave in (pq), there exist a unique pair \((\hat{{p}}^{*},\hat{{q}}^{*})\) that solves (26) subject to (27). Since \(\hat{{p}}(R)\) and \(\hat{{q}}(R)\) are uniquely determined by the equilibrium conditions (8)-(11), there exists a unique \(R^{*}\) such that \(\hat{{p}}^{*}=\hat{{p}}(R^{*})\) and \(\hat{{q}}^{*}=\hat{{q}}(R^{*})\). \(\square \)

Proposition 7

In the no-moral hazard economy with banks and depositors, there exist a unique \(R^{0}\) such that the corresponding equilibrium with intermediation supports the (first best) Pareto optimal allocation.

Proof

Using (18) and \((p^{O},q^{O})\) in (16) and (17), we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle 2\alpha p^{O}=X\left( {W(1-q^{O 2})+2k} \right) \end{aligned}$$
(64)
$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle X^{2}\left( {\frac{W}{2}(1-q^{O 2})+k} \right) ^{2}-\alpha RW(1-q^{O 2})=2\alpha Rq^{O}W \end{aligned}$$
(65)

Equation (64) is independent of R. Solving (65) for R, we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} R^{*}=\frac{\left( {2k+W(1-q^{O 2})} \right) ^{2}X^{2}}{4\alpha W(1+2q^{O}-q^{O 2})}. \end{aligned}$$
(66)

Lastly, we need to verify that \(R^{*}\) is an equilibrium. By proposition 3, this amounts to verify that \(R^{*}\in (\frac{X^{2}k^{2}}{2\alpha W},\frac{X^{2}(W+2k)^{2}}{4\alpha W})\). Thus, \(R^{*}\) is an equilibrium if

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{X^{2}k^{2}}{2\alpha W}<\frac{\left( {2k+W(1-q^{O 2})} \right) ^{2}X^{2}}{4\alpha W(1+2q^{O}-q^{O 2})} \end{aligned}$$
(67)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\left( {2k+W(1-q^{O 2})} \right) ^{2}X^{2}}{4\alpha W(1+2q^{O}-q^{O 2})}<\frac{X^{2}(W+2k)^{2}}{4\alpha W}. \end{aligned}$$
(68)

Rearranging (67), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} 4k^{2}+W^{2}(1-q^{O 2})^{2}+4kW(1-q^{O 2})>2k^{2}(1+2q^{O}-q^{O 2}). \end{aligned}$$
(69)

By assumption, \(k<1\), \(W>1\) and \(0\le q\le 1\). Therefore, \(2k^{2}(1+2q^{O}-q^{O 2})\le 4k^{2}\) and \(W^{2}(1-q^{O 2})^{2}+4kW(1-q^{O 2})>0\). Thus, inequality (69) holds, hence, inequality (67) is verified.

(68) is equivalent to

$$\begin{aligned} 2k+W(1-q^{O 2})<(2k+W)\sqrt{1+2q^{O}-q^{O 2}} \end{aligned}$$
(70)

Since \(1\le 1+2q^{O}-q^{O 2}\le 2\) and\(1-q^{O 2}\le 1\), (70) holds, thus (68) is verified. \(\square \)

Proposition 8

In both the moral-hazard and no-moral hazard economies with banks and depositors, the equilibrium level of risk \(\hat{{p}}\) converges to the optimal level of risk \(p^{*}\) from below, to the optimal level of bank capitalization \(K^{*}\) from above, and to a best allocation as market power rents vanish, i.e. \(\hat{{p}}\uparrow p^{*}\), and \(\hat{{K}}\downarrow K^{*}\) as \(\rho \rightarrow 0\).

Proof

By propositions 2 and 4, \(\hat{{p}}\) increases monotonically in R. By propositions 6 and 7, there exists a unique optimal \(R^{*}\) that supports the optimal level of risk \(p^{*}\). Therefore \(\hat{{p}}(R)\uparrow \hat{{p}}(R^{*})=p^{*}\) and \(\hat{{K}}(R)\downarrow \hat{{K}}(R^{*})=K^{*}\) as \(\rho =R^{*}-R\rightarrow 0\). \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lucchetta, M. Banking competition and welfare. Ann Finance 13, 31–53 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10436-016-0288-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10436-016-0288-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation