Skip to main content
Log in

Sequential payments and optimal pricing in payment systems

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Annals of Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies the intraday payment behaviour between heterogeneous banks as well as optimal intraday pricing schemes. The paper shows the social optimality of payment sequencing, which allows a bank to delay payments until the bank receives payments from the counterparty. The payment sequencing allows a bank with high liquidity cost to ‘recycle’ payment inflow from another bank with lower liqudity cost, reducing the aggregate cost of funding of banks to settle all payments. But we also see that the banks have an incentive to delay payments more than the payment sequencing requires. This underscores the importance of social planner’s role reducing settlement delay, while leaving socially efficient payment sequencing. In this context, we compare two different pricing schemes, a standard throughput guideline and a time-varying intraday tariff, to discuss the optimal incentive mechanisms in payment systems for the ‘socially efficient sequential settlement’.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The banks have to pledge collateral to the central bank to obtain cash, even though the borrowing rate is normally zero across countries. The cost of liquidity is one measure of the opportunity cost of the collateral.

  2. This income transfer from late payers to early payers are ensured through full cost recovery. See Sect. 5.2 for the detail.

  3. The author is grateful for the anonymous referee’s helpful suggestion on this literature.

  4. The distribution over the interval \([t^{begin},t^{end}]\) is assumed to be uniform here, although this is not an essential assumption.

  5. The assumptions A3 and A6 are unnecessary for the proposition. The assumption A7, \(\theta =0\), can be eased to \(\theta \ge 0\), but we need to have \(\alpha +\theta <0\), \(\alpha <0\), to ensure the existence of internal solutions.

  6. If A3 does not hold and if \(\alpha +\delta <0\), then \(E[d_{i}^{1st}]>0\) when \(\mu +2\beta >0\) (a slightly stronger condition than the condition of Proposition 1, since the social planner counts the externality effects of two banks—the intuition of the condition is the same as the Proposition 1). This is because \(\alpha +\delta <0\) implies that the private benefit of own delay (\(\alpha \)) outweighes its negative externality (\(\delta \)). Ie delay is socially optimal until the (net) benefit is dominated by the increase of the delay cost (\(\mu \)). We do not consider this case further since the assumption \(\alpha +\delta <0\) is counterintuitive.

    If \(\alpha +\delta >0\) then \(d_{i}^{1st}\) has a negative constant term. It does change the overall argument below. \(\theta >0\) also provides a negative constant term.

    Even if A6 does not hold and \(\gamma +\eta \ne 0\), the main arguments below are unchanged as long as \(\eta >0\). See “Appendix” for the detail.

  7. If \(\theta >0\) (easing assumption A7) or \(\alpha +\delta \ne 0\) (easing A3), the optimal tariff function takes a slightly different form, because the expected first-best solution has a non-zero constant term, as we have seen in footnote 5.

    Focusing on the case \(\alpha +\delta \ne 0\), \(d_{i}^{1st}\) has a constant term \(\frac{(-1)\left( \alpha +\delta \right) }{\mu +2\beta }\). The optimal tariff function has to incorporate this, so we have the following:

    \(t(d_{i})=t_{0}-\left\{ \alpha -.\frac{\left( \alpha +\delta \right) \left( \mu +\beta \right) }{\mu +2\beta }\right\} \cdot d_{i}\)

    This is still a linear function against \(d_{i}\), and the characteristics of the function are unchanged.

    Assumption A6 is irrelevant to the proposition.

  8. This is what Matsushima (2004) discusses on the review strategy. He aruges that the principle (payment system operator in this case) cannot commit to the review strategy as well, since the principle has an incentive to shorten the review period when the agent (bank) loses the incentive to choose proper payment timing honestly.

  9. To be precise, the actual fee paid is the gross fee minus a lump-sum exemption, so the effective hourly fee is smaller than 1.5 basis point.

  10. For the first 14,000 transfers per month, as of December 2010.

References

  • Armantier, O., Arnold, J., McAndrews, J.: Changes in the timing distribution of fedwire funds transfers. Econ Policy Rev 14(2) (2008). doi:10.2139/ssrn.1141334

  • Angelo, B., Monticini, A.: The intraday price of money: evidence from the e-MID interbank market. J Money Credit Bank 40, 1533–1540 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baglioni, A., Moticini, A.: The intraday price of money: evidence from the e-MID interbank market. J Money Credit Bank 40, 1533–1540 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bech, M.L., Garratt, R.J.: The intraday liquidity management game. J Econ Theory 109, 198–219 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bech, M.L.: Intraday liquidity management: a tale of games banks play. Econ Policy Rev 14(2) (2008). doi:10.2139/ssrn.1141366

  • Buckle, S., Campbell, E.: Settlement bank behaviour and throughput rules in an RTGS payment system with collateralised intraday credit. Bank of England Working Paper 209 (2003)

  • Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems. Real-time gross settlement systems. CPSS Publications 22 (1997)

  • Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems. New developments in large-value payment systems. CPSS Publications 67 (2005)

  • Furfine, C.H.: Banks as monitors of other banks: evidence from the overnight federal funds market. J Bus 74, 33–57 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, J.H., Slutsky, S.M.: Endogenous timing in duopoly games: Stackelberg or Cournot equilibria. Games Econ Behav 2, 29–46 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holthausen, C., Rochet, J.-C.: Efficient pricing of large value interbank payment systems. J Money Credit Bank 38, 1797–1818 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holthausen, C., Rochet, J.-C.: Incorporating a ‘public good factor’ into the pricing of large-value payment systems. European Central Bank Working Paper 507 (2006)

  • Kraenzlin, S., Nellen, T.: Daytime is money. J Money Credit Bank 25, 1689–1702 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manning, M., Nier, E., Schanz, J.: The economics of large-value payments and settlement: theory and policy issues for central banks. Oxford University Press, Oxford (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  • Mailath, G.J.: Endogenous sequencing of firm decisions. J Econ Theory 59, 169–182 (1993)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, A., McAndrews, J.: Liquidity-saving mechanisms. J Monet Econ 55, 554–567 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsushima, H.: Repeated games with private monitoring: two players. Econometrica 72, 823–852 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nellen, T.: Essays in payment economics. Ph.D. Dissertation at the University of Berne (2010)

  • Nellen, T.: Collateralised liquidity, two-part tariff and settlement coordination. SNB Working Papers 13/2015 (2015)

  • van Damme, E., Hurkens, S.: Endogenous Stackelberg leadership. Games Econ Behav 28, 105–129 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vital, C.: Swiss interbank clearing: further experience with a queuing mechanism to control payment system risk. Paper Presented at a Conference on Electronic Banking, Germany (1990)

  • Walsh, C.E.: Optimal contracts for central bankers. Am Econ Rev 85, 150–167 (1995)

    Google Scholar 

  • Willison, M.: Real-time gross settlement and hybrid payment systems: a comparison. Bank of England Working Paper 252 (2005)

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tomohiro Ota.

Additional information

A previous version of this paper was circulated under the title “Intraday two-part tariff in payment systems”, a Bank of England working paper. The views expressed in this paper are those of the author, and not necessarily those of the Bank of England and Goldman Sachs. The author is grateful for the helpful guidance provided by the editor and the anonymous referee. The author also wishes to thank Matthew Brewis, James Chapman, Rodney Garratt, John Jackson, Marius Jurgilas, Thomas Nellen, Ben Norman, Jochen Schanz, Anne Wetherilt, and seminar participants at the Bank of England and Swiss National Bank for their helpful comments and suggestions. Any remaining errors are of course the responsibility of the author.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Proof of Proposition 2

The first-order conditions of the function 6, with respect to \(d_{1}\) and \(d_{2}\) are:

$$\begin{aligned} d_{1}=\frac{(-1)\alpha }{\mu }-\frac{\delta }{\mu }-\frac{\gamma }{\mu } \varepsilon _{1}-\frac{\eta }{\mu }\varepsilon _{2}-\frac{2\beta }{\mu } d_{2}+\frac{\lambda _{1}-\lambda _{3}}{\mu } \end{aligned}$$

That of \(d_{2}\) is defined in the same way. Substituting these and assume \( \lambda _{j}=0\) for all \(j\in \{1,2,3,4\}\), we have:

$$\begin{aligned} d_{1}=\frac{(-1)\left( \alpha +\delta \right) }{\mu }-\frac{\gamma }{\mu } \varepsilon _{1}-\frac{\eta }{\mu }\varepsilon _{2}-\frac{2\beta }{\mu } \left\{ \frac{(-1)\alpha }{\mu }-\frac{\delta }{\mu }-\frac{\eta }{\mu } \varepsilon _{1}-\frac{\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{2}-\frac{2\beta }{\mu } d_{1}\right\} \end{aligned}$$

Solving for \(d_{1}\),

$$\begin{aligned} d_{1}=\frac{(-1)\left( \alpha +\delta \right) }{\mu +2\beta }+\frac{2\beta \gamma -\mu \eta }{\mu ^{2}-4\beta ^{2}}\varepsilon _{2}+\frac{2\beta \eta -\mu \gamma }{\mu ^{2}-4\beta ^{2}}\varepsilon _{1} \end{aligned}$$

From A3 and A6, we have:

$$\begin{aligned} d_{1}= & {} \frac{2\beta \gamma +\mu \gamma }{\mu ^{2}-4\beta ^{2}}\varepsilon _{2}+\frac{-2\beta \gamma -\mu \gamma }{\mu ^{2}-4\beta ^{2}}\varepsilon _{1}\\= & {} \frac{\gamma }{\mu -2\beta }\left( \varepsilon _{2}-\varepsilon _{1}\right) \end{aligned}$$

The first-best solution is, therefore,

$$\begin{aligned} d_{1}^{1st}=\max \left[ \frac{\gamma }{\mu -2\beta }\left( \varepsilon _{2}-\varepsilon _{1}\right) ,0\right] \end{aligned}$$

\(\gamma \left( \mu -2\beta \right) ^{-1}<0\) thus \(d_{1}^{1st}\) is a positive function of \(\varepsilon _{1}\) and a negative function of \( \varepsilon _{2}\). \(\lambda _{1}\) and \(\lambda _{2}\) can be non-zero if \( d_{1}^{1st}=0\): the derivation of these is skipped. Since we have assumed a sufficiently large T, \(\lambda _{3}=\lambda _{4}=0\) in any case. \(\square \)

Appendix 2: Proof of Proposition 4

We keep the assumptions made in Proposition 1, which ensures internal solutions, but we still need to formulate the Kuhn–Tucker conditions because we have the tariff function.

$$\begin{aligned}&\alpha +\mu d_{1}+\beta d_{2}+\gamma \varepsilon _{1}+\frac{\partial t}{ \partial d_{1}}-\lambda _{1}=0 \\&\quad \lambda _{1}\ge 0\text { and }\lambda _{1}d_{1}=0 \end{aligned}$$

The best response function \(d_{1}^{BR}\) is then derived.

$$\begin{aligned} d_{1}^{BR}(E[d_{2}],\varepsilon _{1})=(-1)\frac{\alpha }{\mu }-\frac{\beta }{ \mu }\cdot E\left[ d_{2}(d_{1},\varepsilon _{2})\right] -\frac{\gamma }{\mu } \varepsilon _{1}-\frac{1}{\mu }\left( \frac{\partial t}{\partial d_{1}} -\lambda _{1}\right) \end{aligned}$$

Substitute this into the equation \(E[d_{2}^{BR}(E[d_{1}],\varepsilon _{2})]\) , which is defined in a similar way, and we have:

$$\begin{aligned} E[d_{2}^{BR}(E[d_{1}],\varepsilon _{2})]=\frac{(-1)\alpha }{\mu +\beta }+ \frac{\beta }{\mu ^{2}-\beta ^{2}}\left( \frac{\partial t}{\partial d_{1}} -\lambda _{1}\right) -\frac{\mu }{\mu ^{2}-\beta ^{2}}\left( \frac{\partial t }{\partial d_{2}}-\lambda _{2}\right) \end{aligned}$$

\(E[d_{1}^{BR}(E[d_{2}],\varepsilon _{1})]\) is defined in the same way. We will design the function t to eliminate the source of deadweight loss \( (-1)\alpha \left( \mu +\beta \right) ^{-1}\), so we have the following simultaneous equations:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\alpha }{\mu +\beta }=\frac{\beta }{\mu ^{2}-\beta ^{2}}\left( \frac{ \partial t}{\partial d_{j}}-\lambda _{j}\right) -\frac{\mu }{\mu ^{2}-\beta ^{2}}\left( \frac{\partial t}{\partial d_{i}}-\lambda _{i}\right) \end{aligned}$$

for \(i\ne j\in \{1,2\}\). By solving these equations, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial t}{\partial d_{1}}-\lambda _{1}=\frac{\partial t}{\partial d_{2}}-\lambda _{2}=(-1)\alpha \end{aligned}$$

Integrating these, with \(\lambda _{i}\cdot d_{i}=0\), we have \( t(d_{i})=t_{0}-\alpha d_{i}\). \(\square \)

Appendix 3: Proof of Proposition 5

The aggregate loss of the system under the tariff \(t(d_{i})\) for given \( \varepsilon _{1}\) and \(\varepsilon _{2}\), \(L(d_{1}^{**},d_{2}^{**},c,\varepsilon _{1},\varepsilon _{2})\), is defined as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&L(d_{1}^{**},d_{2}^{**},c,\varepsilon _{1},\varepsilon _{2}) \\&\quad =\alpha \cdot \max \left[ -\frac{\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{1},0\right] +\beta \cdot \max \left[ -\frac{\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{1},0\right] \cdot \max \left[ -\frac{\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{2},0\right] \\&\qquad +\,\gamma \cdot \max \left[ -\frac{\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{1},0\right] \cdot \varepsilon _{1} +\,\delta \cdot \max \left[ -\frac{\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{2},0\right] +\eta \cdot \max \left[ -\frac{\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{2},0\right] \\&\qquad \cdot \varepsilon _{1}+\frac{1}{2}\mu \cdot \max \left[ -\frac{\gamma }{\mu } \varepsilon _{1},0\right] ^{2} +\,\alpha \cdot \max \left[ -\frac{\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{2},0\right] +\beta \cdot \max \left[ -\frac{\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{2},0\right] \\&\qquad \cdot \max \left[ -\frac{\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{1},0\right] +\gamma \cdot \max \left[ -\frac{\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{2},0\right] \cdot \varepsilon _{2} \\&\qquad +\,\delta \cdot \max \left[ -\frac{\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{1},0\right] +\eta \cdot \max \left[ -\frac{\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{1},0\right] \cdot \varepsilon _{2}+\frac{1}{2}\mu \cdot \max \left[ -\frac{\gamma }{\mu } \varepsilon _{2},0\right] ^{2} \end{aligned}$$

If \(\varepsilon _{1}>0\) and \(\varepsilon _{2}>0\), we have:

$$\begin{aligned} L(d_{1}^{**},d_{2}^{**},c,\varepsilon _{1},\varepsilon _{2})= & {} \alpha \frac{-\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}+\beta \frac{-\gamma }{\mu } \varepsilon _{1}\frac{-\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{2}+\gamma \frac{-\gamma }{ \mu }\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{1} \\&+\,\delta \frac{-\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{2}+\eta \frac{-\gamma }{\mu } \varepsilon _{2}\varepsilon _{1}+\frac{1}{2}\mu \left( \frac{-\gamma }{\mu } \varepsilon _{1}\right) ^{2} \\&+\,\alpha \frac{-\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{2}+\beta \frac{-\gamma }{\mu } \varepsilon _{2}\frac{-\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}+\gamma \frac{-\gamma }{ \mu }\varepsilon _{2}\varepsilon _{2} \\&+\,\delta \frac{-\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}+\eta \frac{-\gamma }{\mu } \varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2}+\frac{1}{2}\mu \left( \frac{-\gamma }{\mu } \varepsilon _{2}\right) ^{2} \\= & {} 2\frac{\beta \gamma ^{2}}{\mu ^{2}}\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2}-2 \frac{\eta \gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2}-\frac{1}{2}\frac{ \gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}^{2}-\frac{1}{2}\frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu } \varepsilon _{2}^{2} \\&-\,\left( \alpha +\delta \right) \frac{\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}-\left( \alpha +\delta \right) \frac{\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{2} \end{aligned}$$

From A3 (\(\alpha +\delta =0\)) and A6 (\(\gamma +\eta =0\)), we have:

$$\begin{aligned} L(d_{1}^{**},d_{2}^{**},c,\varepsilon _{1},\varepsilon _{2})= \frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\left\{ 2\frac{\beta +\mu }{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2}-\frac{1}{2}\varepsilon _{1}^{2}-\frac{1}{2}\varepsilon _{2}^{2}\right\} \end{aligned}$$
(8)

Notice that \(L(d_{1}^{**},d_{2}^{**},c,\varepsilon _{1},\varepsilon _{2})\) can be positive when \(\left( \beta +\mu \right) /\mu >\frac{1}{2}\) and \(\varepsilon _{1}\simeq \varepsilon _{2}>0\). If \( \varepsilon _{1}>0\) and \(\varepsilon _{2}\le 0\), \(L(d_{1}^{**},d_{2}^{**},c,\varepsilon _{1},\varepsilon _{2})\) with A3 and A6 is:

$$\begin{aligned} L(d_{1}^{**},d_{2}^{**},c,\varepsilon _{1},\varepsilon _{2})= & {} \alpha \frac{-\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}+\gamma \frac{-\gamma }{\mu } \varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{1}+\frac{1}{2}\mu \left( \frac{-\gamma }{\mu } \varepsilon _{1}\right) ^{2} \\&+\,\delta \frac{-\gamma }{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}+\eta \frac{-\gamma }{\mu } \varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2} \\= & {} \frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2}-\frac{1}{2}\frac{ \gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}^{2} \\\le & {} 0 \end{aligned}$$

Since the banks are almost symmetric, we have a similar welfare for the case \(\varepsilon _{1}\le 0\) and \(\varepsilon _{2}>0\).

$$\begin{aligned} L(d_{1}^{**},d_{2}^{**},c,\varepsilon _{1},\varepsilon _{2})= \frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2}-\frac{1}{2}\frac{ \gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\varepsilon _{2}^{2}\le 0 \end{aligned}$$

If \(\varepsilon _{1}\le 0\) and \(\varepsilon _{2}\le 0\), \(L(d_{1}^{**},d_{2}^{**},c,\varepsilon _{1},\varepsilon _{2})\) is trivially zero.

Substituting these into the Eq. 7:

$$\begin{aligned}&E\left[ L(d_{1}^{**},d_{2}^{**},c,\varepsilon _{1},\varepsilon _{2})\right] \\&\quad =\int _{0}^{\bar{\varepsilon }}\int _{0}^{\bar{ \varepsilon }}\left\{ 2\gamma ^{2}\frac{\beta +\mu }{\mu ^{2}}\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2}-\frac{1}{2}\frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}^{2}- \frac{1}{2}\frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\varepsilon _{2}^{2}\right\} \psi (\varepsilon _{1})\psi (\varepsilon _{2})d\varepsilon _{1}d\varepsilon _{2}\\&\qquad +\int _{0}^{\bar{\varepsilon }}\int _{-\bar{\varepsilon }}^{0}\left\{ \frac{ \gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2}-\frac{1}{2}\frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}^{2}\right\} \psi (\varepsilon _{1})\psi (\varepsilon _{2})d\varepsilon _{1}d\varepsilon _{2} \\&\qquad +\int _{-\bar{\varepsilon }}^{0}\int _{0}^{\bar{\varepsilon }}\left\{ \frac{ \gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2}-\frac{1}{2}\frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}^{2}\right\} \psi (\varepsilon _{1})\psi (\varepsilon _{2})d\varepsilon _{1}d\varepsilon _{2} \end{aligned}$$

The first term can be written as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&\int _{0}^{\bar{\varepsilon }}\int _{0}^{\bar{\varepsilon }}\left\{ 2\gamma ^{2}\frac{\beta +\mu }{\mu ^{2}}\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2}-\frac{1}{2} \frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}^{2}-\frac{1}{2}\frac{\gamma ^{2}}{ \mu }\varepsilon _{2}^{2}\right\} \frac{1}{4\bar{\varepsilon }^{2}} d\varepsilon _{1}d\varepsilon _{2} \\&\quad =\int _{0}^{\bar{\varepsilon }}\left[ \gamma ^{2}\frac{\beta +\mu }{\mu ^{2}} \varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2}^{2}-\frac{1}{2}\frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu } \varepsilon _{1}^{2}\varepsilon _{2}-\frac{1}{6}\frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu } \varepsilon _{2}^{3}\right] _{0}^{\bar{\varepsilon }}\frac{1}{4\bar{ \varepsilon }^{2}}d\varepsilon _{1} \\&\quad = \frac{1}{4\bar{\varepsilon }^{2}}\left[ \frac{1}{2}\gamma ^{2}\frac{\beta +\mu }{\mu ^{2}}\varepsilon _{1}^{2}\bar{\varepsilon }^{2}-\frac{1}{6}\frac{ \gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}^{3}\bar{\varepsilon }-\frac{1}{6}\frac{ \gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\varepsilon _{1}\bar{\varepsilon }^{3}\right] _{0}^{\bar{ \varepsilon }} \\&\quad =\frac{1}{24}\frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\left\{ 3\frac{\beta +\mu }{\mu } -2\right\} \bar{\varepsilon }^{2} \end{aligned}$$

The second term is:

$$\begin{aligned}&\int _{0}^{\bar{\varepsilon }}\left[ \frac{1}{2}\frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu } \varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2}^{2}-\frac{1}{2}\frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu } \varepsilon _{1}^{2}\varepsilon _{2}\right] _{\bar{\varepsilon }}^{0}\frac{1}{ 4\bar{\varepsilon }^{2}}d\varepsilon _{1} \\&\quad =\frac{1}{4\bar{\varepsilon }^{2}}\left[ \frac{1}{6}\frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu } \varepsilon _{1}^{3}\bar{\varepsilon }-\frac{1}{4}\frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu } \varepsilon _{1}^{2}\bar{\varepsilon }^{2}\right] _{0}^{\bar{\varepsilon }}= \frac{1}{48}\frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\left( -1\right) \bar{\varepsilon }^{2} \end{aligned}$$

The third term is equivalent to the second one. Now we have:

$$\begin{aligned} E\left[ L(d_{1}^{**},d_{2}^{**},c,\varepsilon _{1},\varepsilon _{2})\right]= & {} \frac{1}{24}\frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\left\{ 3\frac{\beta +\mu }{\mu }-2\right\} \bar{\varepsilon }^{2}+2\cdot \frac{1}{48} \frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\left( -1\right) \bar{\varepsilon }^{2} \\= & {} \frac{1}{24}\frac{\gamma ^{2}}{\mu }\bar{\varepsilon }^{2}\left( 3\frac{ \beta +\mu }{\mu }-2-1\right) \end{aligned}$$

Since \(\beta <0\), \(\left( \beta +\mu \right) /\mu <1\) and it is sufficient to show the following:

$$\begin{aligned} E\left[ L(d_{1}^{**},d_{2}^{**},c,\varepsilon _{1},\varepsilon _{2})\right] <0 \end{aligned}$$

Since the aggregate loss under the throughput guidelines, \(E\left[ L(0,0,c,\varepsilon _{1},\varepsilon _{2})\right] \) is obviously zero (\( d_{1}=d_{2}=0\) for any cases), now we complete proving that the aggregate loss under the tariff is smaller than the loss under the throughput guidelines. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ota, T. Sequential payments and optimal pricing in payment systems. Ann Finance 12, 441–463 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10436-016-0287-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10436-016-0287-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation