Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Offshoring, domestic outsourcing and productivity: evidence for a number of European countries

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The growth in offshoring and its economic effects have been subject to extensive empirical analysis. Yet, many studies have not distinguished accurately between offshoring, domestic outsourcing, and supplier changes. The present study provides stylized facts on offshoring in Europe between 1995 and 2008 taking into account this distinction. This study shows that service activities have been systematically offshored and outsourced domestically during this period, whereas manufacturing activities have been systematically offshored or moved from domestic to foreign suppliers. Overall the share of internal production has gone down by 4.5 percentage points, which raises the question whether firms have achieved productivity gains through this specialisation effort. Combining industry-level data on offshoring and domestic outsourcing with a firm panel, this study finds that service offshoring and offshoring of non-core manufacturing activities have contributed to an increase in productivity, whereas no statistically significant link is found for offshoring of core manufacturing activities and domestic outsourcing. The estimated productivity gains are found to be driven in particular by the gains of multinational firms.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Olsen (2006) for an early survey of the offshoring-productivity literature.

  2. See Amiti and Wei (2009) for a similar summary of channels for productivity effects.

  3. Henceforth, this study refers only to offshoring, to keep the explanations brief. However, equivalent arguments apply for domestic outsourcing.

  4. The only difference is in the denominator. In Feenstra and Hanson (1999) offshoring is scaled by non-energy inputs, while in this study offshoring is scaled by output.

  5. Australia, Belgium, Canada, the Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Japan, the Republic of Korean, Luxembourg, the Slovak Republic, the United States.

  6. Downloadable at http://www.wiod.org/database/index.htm. See Timmer (2012) for detailed information on the methods applied in the construction of the world input–output table. All information on WIOD presented in the following is taken from this background document.

  7. See Winkler and Milberg (2009) and Castellani et al. (2011) and Feenstra and Jensen (2012) for detailed information on measurement problems in offshoring measures.

  8. For brevity, the nine considered European countries are henceforth often labeled as “Europe”.

  9. Note that the shares of these components in output would sum to 100% if inputs from the primary sector and some remaining service industries (e.g. transport services) were included in the offshoring measures and the domestic outsourcing measures.

  10. Note that the increase in service offshoring and domestic service outsourcing could be also due to newly created services. It is not possible to verify this possibility with input-output data as the composition of internal production (i.e. the share of internal services, core activities, and non-core activities) is unknown.

  11. For detailed graphical representations of offshoring and domestic outsourcing in the time series dimension, see the Online Appendix (figure 1–4).

  12. The TFP estimations were also conducted with the Levinsohn–Petrin method to account for a possible simultaneity bias. Yet, this caused partly implausible point estimates for some of the industries, such as negative coefficients for capital. For this reason the following analysis is based on simple ordinary least square (OLS) estimates of TFP.

  13. See the Online Appendix for a breakdown of the average firm performance by industry.

  14. In order to trace ownership changes over time, an attempt was made to use ownership information from past editions of the Amadeus database, where each of these editions would provide the ownership information at the current point in time. However, this strategy was discarded after careful inspection of the data, since Amadeus does not regularly update the ownership information and since the coverage for these variables is small in the earlier editions.

  15. An increase in offshoring implies by construction a decrease in the internal production if domestic outsourcing is held constant.

  16. An exception is Winkler (2010) who controls for domestic outsourcing using German input–output tables.

  17. It is possible, though, that industry–specific shocks jointly determine firm productivities and world offshoring, in which case the instruments may become invalid. For instance, one may think of a technological invention which raises firm productivity and offshoring simultaneously. While I cannot address this problem in a general way, I am able to rule out biases related to technology by controlling for R&D intensities.

References

  • Amiti, M., & Wei, S. J. (2005). Fear of service outsourcing: Is it justified? Economic Policy, 20(42), 308–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amiti, M., & Wei, S. J. (2009). Service offshoring and productivity: Evidence from the US. World Economy, 32(2), 203–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antràs, P., & Helpman, E. (2004). Global sourcing. Journal of Political Economy, 112(3), 552–580.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blinder, A. S. (2006). Offshoring: The next industrial revolution? Foreign Affairs, 85(2), 113–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blinder, A. S. (2009). How many US jobs might be offshorable? World Economics, 10(2), 41–78.

    Google Scholar 

  • Castellani, D., de Benedictis, L., & Horgos, D. (2011). Can we really trust offshoring indices? (Working Paper 114/2011). Hamburg: Helmut Schmidt University.

  • Egger, H., & Egger, P. (2006). International outsourcing and the productivity of low-skilled labor in the EU. Economic Inquiry, 44(1), 98–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R. C., & Hanson, G. H. (1996). Globalization, outsourcing, and wage inequality. American Economic Review, 86(2), 240–245.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R. C., & Hanson, G. H. (1999). The impact of outsourcing and high-technology capital on wages: Estimates for the United States, 1979–1990. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 907–940.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R. C., & Jensen, J. B. (2012). Evaluating estimates of materials offshoring from U.S. manufacturing (NBER Working Paper 17916). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Geishecker, I. (2007). Assessing the extent and development of international outsourcing in the euro area (Working Paper). University of Göttingen.

  • Geishecker, I., & Görg, H. (2008). Winners and losers: A micro-level analysis of international outsourcing and wages. Canadian Journal of Economics, 41(1), 243–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glass, A. J., & Saggi, K. (2001). Innovation and wage effects of international outsourcing. European Economic Review, 45(1), 67–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Görg, H., & Hanley, A. (2005). International outsourcing and productivity: Evidence from the Irish electronics industry. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 16(2), 255–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Görg, H., & Hanley, A. (2010). Services outsourcing and innovation: An empirical investigation. Economic Inquiry, 49(2), 321–333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Görg, H., Hanley, A., & Strobl, E. (2008). Productivity effects of international outsourcing: Evidence from plant-level data. Canadian Journal of Economics, 41(2), 670–688.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2008). Trading tasks: A simple theory of offshoring. American Economic Review, 98(5), 1978–1997.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hijzen, A., Görg, H., & Hine, R. C. (2005). International outsourcing and the skill structure of labour demand in the United Kingdom. The Economic Journal, 115(506), 860–878.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hijzen, A., Inui, T., & Todo, Y. (2008). Does offshoring pay? Firm-level evidence from Japan. Economic Inquiry, 48(4), 880–895.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hummels, D., Ishii, J., & Yi, K.-M. (2001). The nature and growth of vertical specialization in world trade. Journal of International Economics, 54(1), 75–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohler, W. K., & Wrona, J. (2010). Offshoring tasks, yet creating jobs? (CESifo Working Papers 3019). Munich: Ifo Institute for Economic Research.

  • Mitra, D., & Ranjan, P. (2010). Offshoring and unemployment: The role of search frictions and labor mobility. Journal of International Economics, 81(2), 219–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moulton, B. R. (1990). An illustration of a pitfall in estimating the effects of aggregate variables on micro units. Review of Economics and Statistics, 72(2), 334–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olsen, K. B. (2006). Productivity impacts of offshoring and outsourcing: a review (OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers 2006/1). OECD Publishing.

  • Timmer, M. (2012). The world input-output database (WIOD): Contents, sources and methods (WIOD Working Paper 10). Available at www.wiod.org.

  • Wagner, J. (2011). Offshoring and firm performance: Self-selection, effects on performance, or both? Review of World Economics/Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 147(2), 217–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winkler, D. (2010). Services offshoring and its impact on productivity and employment: Evidence from Germany. 1995–2006. World Economy, 33(12), 1672–1701.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winkler, D., & Milberg, W. (2009). Errors from the “proportionality assumption” in the measurement of offshoring: Application to German labor demand (SCEPA Working Papers 2009–2012). Schwartz Center for Economic Policy Analysis.

Download references

Acknowledgments

I am grateful to Holger Görg, to participants of the Aarhus-Kiel-Workshop 2010, the Göttingen Workshop 2011, and the ISGEP Workshop 2011 in Lüneburg for helpful comments. Research for this paper was supported through the European Commission, Research Directorate General as part of the 7th Framework Programme, Theme 8: Socio-Economic Sciences and Humanities, Grant Agreement no: 244552.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tillmann Schwörer.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (PDF 88 kb).

About this article

Cite this article

Schwörer, T. Offshoring, domestic outsourcing and productivity: evidence for a number of European countries. Rev World Econ 149, 131–149 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-012-0139-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-012-0139-9

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation