Skip to main content
Log in

Oligopolistic vs. monopolistic competition: Do intersectoral effects matter?

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Economic Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Recent extensions of the standard Dixit–Stiglitz (Am Econ Rev 67:297–308, 1977) model, that go beyond the CES sub-utility assumption while maintaining monopolistic competition, have mainly emphasized the role of intrasectoral substitutability. We argue that introducing oligopolistic competition can be an alternative extension, still tractable, allowing to restore the role of intersectoral substitutability and reinforcing the general equilibrium dimension of the model. For this purpose, we define a comprehensive concept of oligopolistic equilibrium to give account of a large set of competition regimes with varying competitive toughness. For two particular regimes, price competition and quantity competition, we show how, with strategic interactions, pro-competitive or anti-competitive effects now depend on the intersectoral elasticity of substitution as compared to the intrasectoral elasticity of substitution.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Notice that Dixit and Stiglitz (1977) have a specific case in mind, the one where the differentiated goods are “good substitutes among themselves, but poor substitutes for the other commodities in the economy” (DS, p. 297). However, this is only a particular case, since in their model a “sector” is defined by a sub-utility, and one cannot exclude some complementarities among goods in the same sector.

  2. Under price competition, we also show that a more productive firm obtains a higher budget share for its differentiated good whenever the intrasectoral elasticity of substitution is large enough, in any case larger than the intersectoral elasticity of substitution.

  3. For example, as mentioned by Bertoletti and Epifani concerning the Melitz–Ottaviano model, “the pro-competitive effect of an increase in market size delivered by this type of preferences in monopolistic competition is entirely driven...by the fact that, just as in Krugman (1979), the elasticity of substitution is decreasing in the level of individual consumption” (2014, section 3.1.1).

  4. We denote \(\partial _{x_{i}}F(\mathbf {x},Y) \equiv \partial F(\mathbf {x},Y)/\partial x_{i}, \partial _{Y}F(\mathbf {x},Y) \equiv \partial F(\mathbf {x},Y) /\partial Y\) and also \(\partial _{i}F(\mathbf {x}) \equiv \partial F(\mathbf {x}) /\partial x_{i}\) when there is no ambiguity. Similarly, \(\partial _{ij}^{2}F(\mathbf {x}) \equiv \partial ^{2}F(\mathbf {x}) /\partial x_{i}\partial x_{j}\) and \(\epsilon _{i}F(\mathbf {x}) \equiv \partial _{i}F(\mathbf {x}) x_{i}/F(\mathbf {x}) \).

  5. Non-rationing of the consumer implies that both constraints are satisfied as equalities for each i at equilibrium. It makes the equilibrium compatible with the consumer’s program and the resulting demand functions.

  6. Otherwise, each firm i would take income Y in its program to be equal to

    $$\begin{aligned} \mathcal {Y}_{i}\left( \left( p_{i},x_{i}\right) ,\left( \mathbf {p} _{-i}^{*},\mathbf {x}_{-i}^{*}\right) \right) =L+\sum _{j\ne i}\left( \left( p_{j}^{*}-c_{j}\right) x_{j}^{*}-\phi _{j}\right) +\left( p_{i}-c_{i}\right) x_{i}-\phi _{i}. \end{aligned}$$

    See Hart (1985) and d’Aspremont et al. (1989, 1990).

  7. To use the terminology of the New Empirical Industrial Organization (see Bresnahan 1989).

  8. This proposition covers the case of CES sub-utility. The case of quadratic sub-utility is analyzed in d’Aspremont and Dos Santos Ferreira (2010).

  9. Producers’ concurrence (‘concours des producteurs’) is the so-called complementary monopoly regime.

  10. This is related to the so-called Bertrand paradox: Tough competition à la Bertrand leads to the competitive outcome even in a (symmetric) duopoly, where each firm gets half of the market.

  11. The reference to the quantity ratio \(x_{i}/Y\), rather than \(x_{i}/z\), when defining the intersectoral elasticity of substitution, is consistent with the choice of \(x_{i}/\underline{X}\), rather than \(x_{i}/x_{j}\), when defining the corresponding intrasectoral concept.

References

  • Atkeson, A., Burstein, A.: Pricing-to-market, trade costs, and international relative prices. Am. Econ. Rev. 98, 1998–2031 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrens, K., Murata, Y.: General equilibrium models of monopolistic competition: a new approach. J. Econ. Theory 136, 776–787 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertoletti, P., Etro, F.: A general theory of endogenous market structures. Ca’ Foscari University of Venice, Department of Economics 09/WP/ 2014

  • Bertoletti, P., Epifani, P.: Monopolistic competition: CES redux? J. Int. Econ. 93, 227–238 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blackorby, C., Russell, R.R.: Will the real elasticity of substitution please stand up? A comparison of the Allen/Uzawa and Morishima elasticities. Am. Econ. Rev. 79, 882–888 (1989)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bresnahan, T.: Empirical studies of industries with market power. In: Schmalansee, R., Willig, R. (eds.) The Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. 2, pp. 1011–1057. Elsevier, Amsterdam (1989)

    Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont, C., Dos Santos Ferreira, R.: Oligopolistic competition as a common agency game. Games Econ. Behav. 70, 21–33 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont, C., Dos Santos Ferreira, R., Gérard-Varet, L.-A.: Unemployment in an extended Cournot oligopoly model. Oxf. Econ. Pap. 41, 490–505 (1989)

    Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont, C., Dos Santos Ferreira, R., Gérard-Varet, L.-A.: On monopolistic competition and involuntary unemployment. Q. J. Econ. 105, 895–919 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont, C., Dos Santos Ferreira, R., Gérard-Varet, L.-A.: On the Dixit–Stiglitz model of monopolistic competition. Am. Econ. Rev. 86, 623–629 (1996)

    Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont, C., Dos Santos Ferreira, R., Gérard-Varet, L.-A.: Competition for market share or for market size: oligopolistic equilibria with varying competitive toughness. Int. Econ. Rev. 48, 761–784 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont, C., Dos Santos Ferreira, R., Gérard-Varet, L.-A.: Strategic R&D investment, competitive toughness and growth. Int. J. Econ. Theory 6, 273–295 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A.K., Stiglitz, J.E.: Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. Am. Econ. Rev. 67, 297–308 (1977)

    Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R.C.: A homothetic utility function for monopolistic competition models, without constant price elasticity. Econ. Lett. 78, 79–86 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O.D.: Imperfect competition in general equilibrium: an overview of recent work. In: Arrow, K.J., Honkapohja, S. (eds.) Frontiers of Economics, pp. 100–149. Basil Blackwell, Oxford (1985)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J.R.: The Theory of Wages. Macmillan, London (1932)

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P.R.: Increasing returns, monopolistic competition, and international trade. J. Int. Econ. 9, 469–479 (1979)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz, M.J.: The impact of trade on intraindustry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71, 1695–1725 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz, M.J., Ottaviano, G.I.P.: Market size, trade, and productivity. Rev. Econ. Stud. 75, 295–316 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nadiri, M.I.: Producers theory. In: Arrow, K.J., Intriligator, M.D. (eds.) Handbook of Mathematical Economics, vol. II, pp. 431–490. North-Holland, Amsterdam (1982)

    Google Scholar 

  • Neary, J.P.: International trade in general oligopolistic equilibrium. Mimeo (2009)

  • Neary, J.P.: Monopolistic competition and international trade theory. In: Brakman, S., Heijdra, B.J. (eds.) The Monopolistic Competition Revolution in Retrospect, pp. 159–184. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  • Parenti, M., Ushchev, P., Thisse, J.-F.: Toward a theory of monopolistic competition. CORE Discussion Paper 2014/46 (2014)

  • Yang, X., Heijdra, B.J.: Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity: comment. Am. Econ. Rev. 83, 295–301 (1993)

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhelobodko, E., Kokovin, S., Parenti, M., Thisse, J.-F.: Monopolistic competition: beyond the constant elasticity of substitution. Econometrica 80, 2765–2784 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Claude d’Aspremont.

Additional information

We are grateful to Mathieu Parenti, Pierre Picard, Jacques Thisse, Philip Ushchev and the seminar and session participants in Saint-Petersburg, Paris, Antwerp and Cambridge for helpful discussion. The usual disclaimer applies.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 The elasticities of substitution

The concept of elasticity of substitution was introduced by Hicks (1932) to measure the response of the input quantity ratio to a variation in the corresponding price ratio, under price taking and cost minimization by the producers. The original concept concerned the case of the sole two inputs, capital and labor, of some production function, but it was later generalized in several ways to the case of an arbitrary number of inputs (see e.g., Blackorby and Russell 1989).

1.1.1 The intrasectoral elasticity of substitution

In this paper, while referring to the sub-utility function X, we consider the elasticity of substitution \(s_{i}\) of good i for the composite good (rather than the elasticity of substitution \(s_{ij}\) between two goods i and j). It is defined, for a bundle of differentiated goods \(\mathbf {x} =\left( x_{1},\ldots ,x_{i},\ldots ,x_{n}\right) \), as the absolute value of the elasticity of the ratio \(x_{i}/X(\mathbf {x}) \) with respect to the marginal rate of substitution \(\partial _{i}X(\mathbf {x}) \), which coincides here with the marginal (sub-)utility of \(x_{i}\):

$$\begin{aligned} s_{i}\equiv -\frac{d\left( x_{i}/X(\mathbf {x}) \right) }{d\left( \partial _{i}X(\mathbf {x}) \right) }\frac{\partial _{i}X(\mathbf {x})}{x_{i}/X(\mathbf {x})}. \end{aligned}$$
(47)

By differentiating \(x_{i}/X(\mathbf {x}) \) and \(\partial _{i}X(\mathbf {x}) \) with respect to \(x_{i}\), we obtain the following expression for the intrasectoral elasticity of substitution of good i:

$$\begin{aligned} s_{i}=\frac{1-\partial _{i}X(\mathbf {x}) x_{i}/X(\mathbf {x})}{-\partial _{ii}^{2}X(\mathbf {x}) x_{i}/\partial _{i}X(\mathbf {x})}. \end{aligned}$$
(48)

Notice that \(s_{i}\) can be seen as the reciprocal of the degree of curvature of the graph \(\left( x_{i}/X(\mathbf {x}),X(\mathbf {x}) \right) \).

The elasticity of substitution between goods i and j is:

$$\begin{aligned} s_{ij}\equiv & {} -\frac{d(x_{i}/x_{j})}{d\left( dx_{j}/dx_{i}\right) }\frac{dx_{j}/dx_{i}}{x_{i}/x_{j}} \\= & {} {\tiny -}\frac{\partial _{i}X(\mathbf {x}) \partial _{j}X(\mathbf {x}) \left( x_{i}\partial _{i}X(\mathbf {x}) +x_{j}\partial _{j}X(\mathbf {x}) \right) }{x_{i}x_{j}\left( \partial _{ii}^{2}X(\mathbf {x}) \left( \partial _{j}X(\mathbf {x}) \right) ^{2}-2\partial _{ij}^{2}X(\mathbf {x}) \partial _{i}X(\mathbf {x}) \partial _{j}X(\mathbf {x}) +\partial _{jj}^{2}X(\mathbf {x}) \left( \partial _{i}X(\mathbf {x}) \right) ^{2}\right) } \nonumber \end{aligned}$$
(49)

(see Nadiri 1982). If sub-utility X is symmetric and if we consider any pair (ij) of goods such that \(x_{i}=x_{j}=x\),

$$\begin{aligned} s_{ij}=\frac{1}{-\partial _{ii}^{2}X(\mathbf {x}) x/\partial _{i}X(\mathbf {x}) +\partial _{ij}^{2}X(\mathbf {x}) x/\partial _{i}X(\mathbf {x})}, \end{aligned}$$
(50)

which converges to the same value as our elasticity \(s_{i}\) as n tends to infinity, implying that \(\partial _{i}X(\mathbf {x}) x_{i}/X(\mathbf {x}) \rightarrow 0\) and \(\partial _{ij}^{2}X(\mathbf {x}) x/\partial _{i}X(\mathbf {x}) \rightarrow 0\) (cf. Parenti et al. 2014, where the set of the differentiated goods is a continuum). Also, symmetry and constancy of the elasticity \(s_{ij}\) (\(s_{ij}=s\) for any \(\mathbf {x}\) and any pair \(\left( i,j\right) \) of goods), corresponding to the CES sub-utility function \( X(\mathbf {x}) =\left( \sum _{i=1}^{n}a_{i}x_{i}^{(s-1) /s}\right) ^{s/(s-1)}\), naturally lead to the coincidence of both elasticities: \(s_{i}=s_{ij}=s\). By applying (48), we indeed obtain at \(\mathbf {x}\):

$$\begin{aligned} s_{i}=\frac{1-a_{i}\left( x_{i}/X(\mathbf {x}) \right) ^{(s-1) /s}}{\left( 1-a_{i}\left( x_{i}/X(\mathbf {x}) \right) ^{(s-1) /s}\right) /s}=s. \end{aligned}$$
(51)

Thus, the elasticity \(s_{i}\) of intrasectoral substitution to which we refer in this paper coincides with the standard elasticity \(s_{ij}\) in two of the most used cases in the literature, namely the case of the CES sub-utility function and the case of a “large group” of differentiated goods (justifying the monopolistic competition approach), when the sub-utility function X and the observed basket \(\mathbf {x}\) are both symmetric.

The intrasectoral elasticity of substitution \(s_{i}\) can alternatively be computed in terms of prices (under consumer price taking and expenditure minimizing). To do that, denoting \(\underline{X}=X(\mathbf {x}) \), we refer to the shadow price of the composite good \(\underline{P}\equiv \partial _{X}e\left( \mathbf {p,}\underline{X}\right) \), and use the expression of \(x_{i}\) given by Shephard’s lemma (3):

$$\begin{aligned} s_{i}=-\frac{d\left( x_{i}/\underline{X}\right) }{d\left( p_{i}/\underline{P} \right) }\frac{p_{i}/\underline{P}}{x_{i}/\underline{X}}=-\frac{d\left( \partial _{p_{i}}e\left( \mathbf {p,}\underline{X}\right) /\underline{X} \right) }{d\left( p_{i}/\underline{P}\right) }\frac{p_{i}/\underline{P}}{\partial _{p_{i}}e\left( \mathbf {p,}\underline{X}\right) /\underline{X}} . \end{aligned}$$
(52)

By differentiating \(\partial _{p_{i}}e\left( \mathbf {p,}\underline{X}\right) /\underline{X}\) and \(p_{i}/\underline{P}\) with respect to \(p_{i}\), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} s_{i}=\frac{-\partial _{p_{i}p_{i}}^{2}e\left( \mathbf {p,}\underline{X} \right) p_{i}/\partial _{p_{i}}e\left( \mathbf {p,}\underline{X}\right) }{1-\partial _{p_{i}X}^{2}e\left( \mathbf {p,}\underline{X}\right) p_{i}/\partial _{X}e\left( \mathbf {p,}\underline{X}\right) } \end{aligned}$$
(53)

and, by using the definition of the Hicksian demand \(H_{i}\) in (3), together with the first-order condition (2), we finally get

$$\begin{aligned} s_{i}=\frac{-\epsilon _{p_{i}}H_{i}\left( \mathbf {p,}\underline{X}\right) }{1-\left[ \epsilon _{i}X(\mathbf {x}) \right] \left[ \epsilon _{X}H_{i}\left( \mathbf {p,}\underline{X}\right) \right] }. \end{aligned}$$
(54)

1.1.2 The intersectoral elasticity of substitution

To define the intersectoral elasticity of substitution of good i, we refer to the quantity ratio \(x_{i}/Y\) (instead of \(x_{i}/\underline{X}\)),Footnote 11 implicitly taking into account the variation of the Marshallian demand D (rather than sticking to the mere share adjustment as measured by \(-\epsilon _{p_{i}}H_{i}\left( \mathbf {p,}\underline{X}\right) \)). The corresponding price ratio is of course \(p_{i}/1=p_{i}\). So, the intersectoral elasticity of substitution \(\sigma _{i}\) of good i can be expressed as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \sigma _{i}\equiv -\left. \frac{d(x_{i}/Y) }{dp_{i}}\right| _{X(\mathbf {x}) =D(\mathbf {p},Y)}\frac{p_{i}}{x_{i}/Y}=-\frac{\left( 1/Y\right) \partial _{p_{i}}D\left( \mathbf {p},Y\right) }{\partial _{i}X(\mathbf {x})}\frac{p_{i}}{x_{i}/Y}= \frac{-\epsilon _{p_{i}}D(\mathbf {p},Y)}{\epsilon _{i}X(\mathbf {x})}. \end{aligned}$$
(55)

To illustrate, take the case of the utility function introduced in Sect. 2.4:

$$\begin{aligned} U(X(\mathbf {x}),z)= & {} \frac{b^{1/\sigma }}{1-1/\sigma }X(\mathbf {x})^{1-1/\sigma }+z, \\ \text {with}\;\;X(\mathbf {x})= & {} \left( \sum _{i=1}^{n}x_{i}^{(s-1) /s}\right) ^{s/(s-1)},\quad \sigma >1\;\;\text {and}\;\;b>0. \nonumber \end{aligned}$$
(56)

The corresponding Marshallian demand for the composite good is the isoelastic function

$$\begin{aligned} D(\mathbf {p},Y) =bP(\mathbf {p})^{-\sigma },\quad \text {with }\quad P(\mathbf {p}) =\left( \sum _{i=1}^{n}p_{i}^{1-s}\right) ^{1/(1-s)}, \end{aligned}$$
(57)

so that we obtain the following expression for the intersectoral elasticity of substitution, as defined by (55):

$$\begin{aligned} \sigma _{i}=\sigma \frac{\left( p_{i}/P(\mathbf {p}) \right) ^{1-s}}{\left( x_{i}/X(\mathbf {x}) \right) ^{(s-1) /s}}=\sigma , \end{aligned}$$
(58)

since \(x_{i}=\left( p_{i}/P(\mathbf {p}) \right) ^{-s}X(\mathbf {x})\) when the \(x_{i}\)’s are chosen optimally. Thus, the intersectoral elasticity of substitution is symmetric and constant in this case (\(\sigma _{i}=\sigma \) for any i), equal to the elasticity of the demand for the composite good.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

d’Aspremont, C., Dos Santos Ferreira, R. Oligopolistic vs. monopolistic competition: Do intersectoral effects matter?. Econ Theory 62, 299–324 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-015-0905-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-015-0905-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation