Skip to main content

Longstanding Sources of Instability: The Current Deficits of the Economic Union

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 230 Accesses

Part of the book series: Studies in European Economic Law and Regulation ((SEELR,volume 18))

Abstract

This chapter will identify the main deficits, which are preventing the economic governance from fully achieving the objective of the stability of the euro area as a whole. These are essentially three. First, the limits of the existing legal basis have been the cause of the legal incoherence of the reforms, as well as the wide use of intergovernmental agreements beyond EU law (so called ‘flight into international law’). Second, the reforms introduced to fulfil consolidation and stabilisation policies in the euro area have proven to be substantially ineffective, meaning unable to contribute to the cause of stability. This depends on the scarce credibility of economic sanctions and legal prohibitions, as well as the wide political discretion of the peer-review surveillance on national economic policies. Finally, the democratic deficit has prevented the governance from fully taking into consideration the requests and interests of the people affected by its policies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   109.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See Decision 2010/281 of the European Central Bank of 14 May 2010 establishing a Securities Markets Programme; Decisions of the Governing Council of the European Central Bank (ECB) of 6 September 2012 on a number of technical features regarding the Eurosystem’s outright monetary transactions in secondary sovereign bond markets (the OMT decisions); Press Release of the ECB, 22 January 2015 (Quantitative Easing decision).

  2. 2.

    European Commission Proposal for a Council Regulation (2017).

  3. 3.

    Schwarz (2014), Ziller (2015), p. 28; Lo Schiavo (2017), p. 143.

  4. 4.

    See ECJ Judgment of 27 November 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, ECLI:EU:C:2012:756, para. 167. On the use of enhanced cooperation see Tuori and Tuori (2014), p. 175.

  5. 5.

    Art. 136 TFEU may represent the ‘locus of true expansion’ for new competences to the EU. See Ioannidis (2016), p. 1270. Accordingly, the norm may behave similarly to art. 114 TFUE for the setup of the single market. See Beukers (2013), pp. 11–12.

  6. 6.

    Leino-Sandberg and Salminen (2017), p. 77. Notably recommendations are non-binding and their legality cannot be reviewed by the ECJ . It is nevertheless unlikely that the mandate under art. 121 TFEU, also in combination with art. 136 TFEU, allows to pass from non-binding instruments to binding instruments. Ibid., p. 78.

  7. 7.

    On the innovative nature of the reverse majority voting see Bauer and Becker (2014), pp. 219–220; Seikel (2016), pp. 1405–1408.

  8. 8.

    Häde (2010), p. 921; Ruffert (2011), pp. 1800–1806; Calliess (2011–2012), p. 116; Fischer-Lescano and Oberndorfer (2013), p. 12; Ohler (2014), p. 128; Palmstorfer (2014), pp. 201–202; Tuori and Tuori (2014), pp. 170–171; Grimm (2016), pp. 132, 145.

  9. 9.

    Notably art. 16(3) TEU states that the Council shall always act by standard qualified majority, except where the Treaties provide otherwise. Also, the Court of Justice has interpreted the principle of conferral in the sense that EU institutions shall not modify the norms regulating their own functioning, except if the Treaty expressly allows them to do so. See ECJ , Judgment of 6 May 2008, Case C-133/06, European Parliament v Council of the European Union, ECLI:EU:C:2008: 257, para 54.

  10. 10.

    See Leino-Sandberg and Salminen (2017), p. 78.

  11. 11.

    Palmstorfer (2014), p. 197.

  12. 12.

    In this regard, it should be noted that art. 126(13) TFEU refers specifically to the use of standard qualified majority to be defined in accordance with art. 238(3) TFEU.

  13. 13.

    Palmstorfer (2014), p. 201.

  14. 14.

    The choice of art. 121(6) TFEU depended on the fact that art. 136(1) TFEU expressly excludes the procedures set out in art. 126(14) TFEU from its margin of action. On this topic see Antpöhler (2012), p. 378.

  15. 15.

    Cf. Palmstorfer (2014), pp. 196–197.

  16. 16.

    Some authors tried to argue the legality of the RMV on the fact, they apply only to new sanctions , which are not mentioned in primary law, thus avoiding any direct conflict with the EU Treaty. Others suggested, semi-automatic sanctions might be qualified as implementing acts of the Commission, which might be justified on the basis of art. 291(2) TFEU. Cf. Palmstorfer (2014), pp. 199–201. More in general, even if semi-automatic sanctions aim to change the nature of coordination, thus posing a potentially threat to the conferral principle, their introduction should still be accepted as long as they succeed making budgetary discipline more effective. See Allemand and Martucci (2012), p. 72; Beukers (2013), p. 15.

  17. 17.

    If the norms of the Six Pack are not consistent with primary law, they may be subject to an action for annulment ex art. 263 TFEU. However, such perspective has now become impossible, because art. 263(6) TFEU sets a deadline of 2 months from the publication of the act to start an annulment procedure. A preliminary-reference procedure is unlikely, but not impossible. See Palmstorfer (2014), p. 202.

  18. 18.

    See Calliess (2012), p. 108; Allemand and Martucci (2012), p. 78; De Streel and Etienne (2012), pp. 184–185; Baratta (2013), p. 52.

  19. 19.

    The fact that the ESM is an autonomous legal entity with legal personality, distinct from the participating Member States does not make it fall outside art. 125 TFEU. The ESM is in fact an emanation of the participating Member States, which are its owners. Like the EFSF, the ESM is assimilated to the Member States in the sense of art. 125 TFEU and fall within its scope of application ratione personae. See View of Advocate General Kokott delivered on 26 October 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, ECLI:EU:C:2012:675, para. 110; De Gregorio Merino (2012), p. 1626; Tuori and Tuori (2014), p. 123.

  20. 20.

    See Ruffert (2011), p. 1785; Hoffmeister (2011), pp. 120–123; Hentschelmann (2011), p. 286; Ruffert (2013), p. 258; Manzini (2013), pp. 38–40; Häde (2016), Artikel 125 AEUV, paras 11, 12; Grimm (2016), pp. 81–83; Ketterer (2016), p. 248.

  21. 21.

    In this sense, the principle of no-bailout follows the principle of subsidiarity. See Tufano (2002), p. 508.

  22. 22.

    According to art. 25(2) TESM, if a Member State fails to meet the required payment under a capital call, a revised increased capital call shall be made to all the other countries. This may be in contrast with the no bailout principle. See Beck (2014), pp. 548–549.

  23. 23.

    See Ketterer (2016), pp. 217–218.

  24. 24.

    See Ruffert (2013), p. 258; Tomkin (2013), p. 75; Beck (2014), pp. 547–548; Ketterer (2016), pp. 229–231; Grimm (2016), pp. 66–69.

  25. 25.

    On the sovereign debt crisis in Cyprus cf. Vellano (2013).

  26. 26.

    See Ruffert (2011), p. 1786; De Witte and Beukers (2013), pp. 842–843; Ketterer (2016), pp. 232–233.

  27. 27.

    See Hoffmeister (2011), p. 122. Furthermore, art. 125 TFEU consists of a lex generalis, against the lex specialis of art. 122(2) TFEU, which allows the provision of financial support in exceptional circumstances. If financial support could be always given, there was no need for art. 122 (2) TFEU. See Ketterer (2016), pp. 223–224.

  28. 28.

    Most academic doctrine does not share an absolute interpretation of art. 125 TFEU. See Tosato (2010), Herrmann (2010), p. 415; Della Cananea (2011), Thymes and Wendel (2012), pp. 743–748, 754; Smits (2012), p. 828; Bandilla (2017), Artikel 25 AEUV, paras 31–32.

  29. 29.

    ECJ Judgment of 27 November 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, para. 130.

  30. 30.

    Ibid. para. 132.

  31. 31.

    Ibid. para. 131.

  32. 32.

    Ibid. paras. 135–136. Beck strongly criticised the Pringle judgment for the exasperation of the teleological approach and extreme literal interpretation, which leads it to absurdity. See Beck (2014), pp. 548–549.

  33. 33.

    ECJ Judgment of 27 November 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, para. 136.

  34. 34.

    Cf. supra Sect. 3.6.3.

  35. 35.

    See ECJ Judgment of 27 November 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, ECLI:EU:C:2012:756, para. 135. On the ultima ratio interpretation see Tuori (2012), pp. 24–25.

  36. 36.

    The Court comes to this opinion also considering the preparatory works relating to the Treaty of Maastricht according to which the aim of art. 125 TFEU is to ensure that Member States follow a sound budgetary policy . See ECJ Judgment of 27 November 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, ECLI:EU:C:2012:756, para. 135. Borger noticed that the Court could not present the objective of safeguarding the financial stability of the monetary union as a new interpretation of art. 125 TFEU following from Decision 2011/199/EU, as this would have led to an implicit modification of the no bailout clause . See Borger (2013b), p. 135.

  37. 37.

    Tuori and Tuori call it the ‘two-level teleology’. See Tuori and Tuori (2014), p. 129.

  38. 38.

    See ECJ Judgment of 27 November 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, ECLI:EU:C:2012:756, para. 136.

  39. 39.

    View of Advocate General Kokott delivered on 26 October 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, ECLI:EU:C:2012:675, para 139.

  40. 40.

    Ibid. para 140.

  41. 41.

    In favour of the consistency of rescue mechanism with the principle of solidarity see Borger (2013a), pp. 25–26; Bandilla (2017) Artikel 25 AEUV, para 31.

  42. 42.

    View of Advocate General Kokott delivered on 26 October 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, ECLI:EU:C:2012:675, paras 142–143.

  43. 43.

    According to some authors, the Court supported a new interpretation of art. 125 TFEU with the intention to provide a judicial legitimation to a political decision. See Kerber (2013), pp. 10–11; Beck (2014), p. 550.

  44. 44.

    Borger identifies two concepts of solidarity. ‘Factual solidarity’ is a result of the mutual interdependence between Member States of the Union. The introduction of a single currency has indeed strengthened integration within the euro area, making the default of one Member State dangerous for the economic stability of the others. On the other hand, ‘normative solidarity’ derives from the belonging of Member States to the same community and the pursuit of the common good. Evidently both dimensions of the principle apply in relation to the rescue strategy adopted to deal with the sovereign debt crisis. See Borger (2013a), pp. 10–11.

  45. 45.

    The CJEU indeed stressed that assistance granted by the ESM does not consist of subsides, but of loans, which must be paid to the ESM, including an appropriate margin. See ECJ Judgment of 27 November 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, ECLI:EU:C:2012:756, para. 139. Iaonnidis noticed, however, the credit provided by the ESM contains ‘subsidized interest rates that are significantly lower than market rates’. Ioannidis (2016), p. 1260. The purchase of bonds on the secondary market is legally controversial, as it sorts the effect of discharging the issuing state’s commitment to the former creditor and to upset normal market conditions. See Tuori and Tuori (2014), p. 126; Schepel (2017), p. 88.

  46. 46.

    The crisis might have determined an ‘Abirrung der Markte’ (aberration/mistake of the markets), which prevents it from having a regulatory role. See Nettesheim (2012), p. 63. Markets have not always been able to exercise an effective regulatory role. Cf. De Gregorio Merino (2012), p. 1627; Tuori and Tuori (2014), pp. 127–128.

  47. 47.

    ECJ , Judgment of 16 June 2015, Case C-62/14, Gauweiler (and Others) v. Deutscher Bundestag, ECLI:EU:C:2015:400, paras 72, 74.

  48. 48.

    ‘Spreads always only result from the market participants’ expectations and are, regardless of their rationality, essential for market-based pricing. To single out and neutralise supposedly identifiable individual causes would be tantamount to an arbitrary interference with market [..]. Ultimately, the distinction between rational and irrational is meaningless in this context and can in any case not be operationalised’. Order of German Federal Constitutional Court , 14 January 2014, [2 BvR 2728/13], para 98.

  49. 49.

    Cf. Ioannidis (2016), p. 1259.

  50. 50.

    See Richter (2013), Article 125 TFEU, para 5.

  51. 51.

    A number of economists and think tanks have already developed some detailed analysis on the project, highlighting the technical options and the legal challenges of the so called ‘Eurobonds ’. The European Commission itself endorsed the idea of Eurozone-joint stability bond in a Green Paper published in 2011. See European Commission Communication (2011).

  52. 52.

    See Adamski (2012), p. 1331; Craig (2013), p. 9.

  53. 53.

    In this regard Adamski believes that Greece received ‘funds on preferential terms’. Adamski (2012), p. 1331. On the sustainability of Greek debt cf. infra Sects. 4.3.3.2 and 5.3.2.1.2.

  54. 54.

    See Eurogroup statement on Greece , 15 June 2018. Greece officially concluded its ESM financial assistance programme in August 2018. It should be noted that in May 2019 the EFSF decided to the return to Greece €103 million euros paid between January 1 to 17 June 2018, in relation to an interest rate hike provided by the MoU , and to suspend a similar increase related to the period June 17, 2018-June 17, 2019, which will save the Greek government € 226 million. See Press Release, ‘ESM formally approves more than 970 million of debt relief for Greece ’, 2 May 2019.

  55. 55.

    De Witte and Beukers (2013), pp. 839–840; Cisotta (2015), pp. 291–292; Palm (2017), Artikel 136 AEUV, para. 57.

  56. 56.

    Thymes and Wendel (2012), p. 748.

  57. 57.

    In Decision 2011/199/EU amending art. 136 TFEU the European Council clearly stated that art. 122(2) TFEU shall not be applied to safeguard the financial stability of the euro area. See Whereas (4) European Council Decision 2011/199/EU.

  58. 58.

    The fiscal crisis in countries like Greece does not fit definition as it is the consequence of chronical budgetary mismanagement. See De Gregorio Merino (2012), p. 1634; Vogel (2012), pp. 463–464; Tosato (2012) p. 687; De Witte and Beukers (2013), p. 810.

  59. 59.

    ECJ Judgment of 27 November 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, ECLI:EU:C:2012:756, paras 65, 120.

  60. 60.

    See ECJ Judgment of 27 November 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, ECLI:EU:C:2012:756, para. 69.

  61. 61.

    Ibid. paras 112–113.

  62. 62.

    See De Lhoneux and Vassilopoulos (2013), p. 44; Schwarz (2014), p. 412; Poulou (2017), pp. 996–997.

  63. 63.

    See art. 10, art. 11, art. 12 and art. 13 of Regulation (EU) No 472/2013.

  64. 64.

    Memorandum of Understanding on Specific Economic Policy Conditionality (Second Economic Adjustment Programme for Greece ), March 2012.

  65. 65.

    Before 2013, the measures directed to countries that received assistance from the EFSF or the ESM, except from formally non-binding Memoranda of Understanding, also took the form of decisions of the Council ex art. 126(6) or (9) TFEU together with art. 136 TFEU. See Ioannidis (2016), p. 1269.

  66. 66.

    The Council decision approving the MAP is binding and its legality can be reviewed by the ECJ . See Leino-Sandberg and Salminen (2017), p. 78. Looking more into details, they have a similar content, but not identical. In particular, the MoUs are longer and more detailed than the decisions of the Council. The loan agreement between the recipient country and the ESM recalls both documents, by acknowledging they have the same legal status. See Poulou (2017), p. 1002.

  67. 67.

    ECJ Judgment of 20 September 2016, Joined Cases C-8/15 P to C-10/15 P, Ledra Advertising Ltd. and Others v European Commission and European Central Bank (ECB), ECLI:EU:C:2016:701. Cf. Estella (2018), pp. 226–231.

  68. 68.

    Ioannidis (2014), pp. 34–35. Conditionality policy consists of a form of ‘imposition’, rather than coordination. Munari (2018), p. 362.

  69. 69.

    Art. 12 (1) TESM states that conditionality may range ‘from a macro-economic adjustment programme to continuous respect of pre-established eligibility conditions’ and ‘it should reflect the severity of the weakness to be addresses and the financial assistance chosen. According to art. 7(1) of Regulation (EU) No 472/2013, ‘macroeconomic adjustment programme shall address the specific risks emanating from that Member State for the financial stability in the euro area and shall aim at rapidly re-establishing a sound and sustainable economic and financial situation and restoring the Member State’s capacity to finance itself fully on the financial markets’.

  70. 70.

    Cf. Rossolillo (2018), p. 141.

  71. 71.

    See Tuori and Tuori (2014), p. 189; Ioannidis (2016), pp. 1271–1272.

  72. 72.

    The influence that the ESM can exercise on the budgetary policy of Member States depends on their financial strength, and indirectly on their populations (as decisions are taken on the basis of capital contribution). See Dawson and de Witte (2013), p. 838.

  73. 73.

    Munari (2015), pp. 741–743.

  74. 74.

    Order of the General Court, 27 November 2012, Case T-541/10, Anotati Dioikisi Enoseon Dimosion Ypallilon (ADEDY) and Others v Council of the European Union, ECLI:EU:T:2012:626.

  75. 75.

    ECJ Judgment of 27 November 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, ECLI:EU:C:2012:756, para.180.

  76. 76.

    ECJ Judgement of 20 September 2016, Joined Cases C-105/15 P to C-109/15 P, Konstantinos Mallis and Others v European Commission and European Central Bank (ECB), ECLI:EU:C:2016:702. For an analysis of the case cf. Cafari Panico (2017), pp. 295–296.

  77. 77.

    In Åklagaren case the CJEU clarified that ‘the fundamental rights guaranteed by the Charter must [..] be complied with where national legislation falls within the scope of European Union law’. ECJ judgment of 26 February 2013, Case C-617/10, Åklagaren v Hans Åkerberg Fransson, ECLI:EU:C:2013:105, para 21. Accordingly, the EUCFR should be applied when there is direct link between a national (austerity) measure and an act of the Union, meaning any lacuna in the implementation of the austerity measures may cause a violation of both the MoU and the Council Decision ex art. 7(2) of Regulation (EU) No 472/2013, thus leading to a suspension of financial assistance . On the relevance of the Åklagaren case law see Pistoia (2018), pp. 83–84.

  78. 78.

    On the hybrid nature of conditionality policy cf. Sect. 4.2.6.

  79. 79.

    On the connection between conditionality and EU law see Hinarejos (2015), pp. 134–135; Craig (2017), p. 245. Poulou recalls the Wachauf judgment (ECJ Judgment of 13 July 1989, Hubert Wachauf v Bundesamt für Ernährung und Forstwirtschaft, C-5/88, ECLI:EU:C:1989:321), according to which Member States act like agents of the Union, why they apply regulations, directives or decisions of the Council. Poulou (2017), pp. 1021–1022. In the Florescu case, the Court has qualified a MoU stipulated between the European Commission and Romania in the framework of financial assistance ex art. 143 TFEU, as an act of EU law. The latter can be therefore subject to an action of annulment. The Court based its decision on the fact that the MoU has a clear legal basis in the EU Treaties and it was concluded with the European Union. See ECJ Judgment of 13 June 2017, Case C-258/12, Eugenia Florescu and Others v Casa Judeţeană de Pensii Sibiu and Others, ECLI:EU:C:2017:448. On the analysis of the case cf. Markakis and Dermine (2018).

  80. 80.

    Bernard (2013), p. 267.

  81. 81.

    ‘[T]he Member States are entitled, in areas which do not fall under the exclusive competence of the Union, to entrust tasks to the institutions, outside the framework of the Union, [..] provided that those tasks do not alter the essential character of the powers conferred on those institutions by the EU and FEU Treaties’. ECJ Judgment of 27 November 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, ECLI:EU:C:2012:756, para 158.

  82. 82.

    ECJ Judgment of 20 September 2016, Joined Cases C-8/15 P to C-10/15 P, Ledra Advertising Ltd and Others v European Commission and European Central Bank (ECB), ECLI:EU:C:2016:701.

  83. 83.

    The applicability of the EUCFR to the Council should be less controversial as it participated in the definition of conditionality policy through a decision adopted in accordance with Regulation (EU) No 472/2013.

  84. 84.

    For an analysis of the case cf. Poulou (2017), pp. 1008–1009, 1013–1014; Cafari Panico (2017), pp. 293–295.

  85. 85.

    ECJ Judgement of 13 July 2018, Case T-680/13, Dr. K. Chrysostomides & Co. LLC and Others v Council of the European Union and Others, ECLI:EU:T:2018:486, paras 109–110; ECJ Judgment, Case T-786/14, 13 July 2018, Eleni Pavlikka Bourdouvali and Others v Council of the European Union and Others, ECLI:EU:T:2018:487, paras 105–106. It should be noted that the Council has appealed both rulings. See C-597/18 P; C-598/18 P). An action of annulment is excluded because the Eurogroup is not an EU body within the meaning of art. 263 TFEU. Ibid. para. 105.

  86. 86.

    Poulou (2017), pp. 1012–1013.

  87. 87.

    ECJ Judgment of 20 September 2016, Joined Cases C-8/15 P to C-10/15 P, Ledra Advertising Ltd and Others v European Commission and European Central Bank (ECB), ECLI:EU:C:2016:701, para. 71. The strengthening of economic integration has determined a compression of social rights of EU citizens. It is regrettable the CJEU has normally preferred to privilege the sustainability of public finances over the protection of fundamental individual rights. On the relevant case law cf. Cafari Panico (2017), pp. 306–311. On the possible ways to balance fiscal stability with the protection of the fundamental rights in the EU legal system cf. Condinanzi (2016), pp. 249–252.

  88. 88.

    See Häde (2012), pp. 15–16.

  89. 89.

    See Craig (2012), pp. 238–241; Tomkin (2013), pp. 79–81, Dimopoulos (2014), pp. 62–63.

  90. 90.

    Delors ‘Report on Economic and Monetary Union in the European Community’, 17th April 1989, p. 14.

  91. 91.

    Miglio (2015), pp. 157–158.

  92. 92.

    In perspective, the TSCG does foresee an incorporation clause, according to which within 5 years of the date of entry into force of the Treaty, the Member States shall take the necessary step to incorporate its substance into the legal framework of the EU.

  93. 93.

    See ECJ Judgment of 27 November 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, ECLI:EU:C:2012:756, paras 92, 101. According to Munari, in the Pringle case the CJEU allowed Member States to sign intergovernmental agreements that overlap EU competences but are external to the Union, as long as these international obligations respect EU law. This represents a step backwards with regards to the parallelism of internal and external competences affirmed in in the ERTA case law. Munari (2015), p. 735; Munari (2018), p. 360.

  94. 94.

    Art. 1 TSCG explains the Fiscal Compact aims to ‘strengthen the economic pillar of the Economic and Monetary Union by adopting a set of rules intended to foster budgetary discipline through a fiscal compact , to strengthen the coordination of their economic policies and to improve the governance of the euro area’. Art. 3 TESM states that ‘the ESM shall be to mobilise funding and provide stability support under strict conditionality , appropriate to the financial assistance instrument chosen, to the benefit of ESM Members which are experiencing, or are threatened by, severe financing problems’.

  95. 95.

    Art. 3 TESM recalls the objective. The TSCG explains in the Preamble that the strengthening of fiscal consolidation, which is the formal objective of the agreement, aims to pursue the stability of the euro area as a whole .

  96. 96.

    Calliess (2012), p. 105.

  97. 97.

    See ECJ Judgment of 27 November 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, ECLI:EU:C:2012:756, paras. 120–121.

  98. 98.

    Notably the ‘comunitarisation’ of the intergovernmental procedures started by the Two Pack aimed to avoid inconsistencies between the MoU and EU law. See supra Sect. 3.6.3.

  99. 99.

    ECJ Judgment of 27 November 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, ECLI:EU:C:2012:756, paras 170–177. On the role of the CJEU in the TESM cf. Miglio (2015), pp. 162–166; Pistoia (2018), pp. 92–96. According Ziller the conferral of this task to the CJEU is the only provision of the TSCG, which could not have been adopted on the basis of secondary law. Ziller (2015), p. 29.

  100. 100.

    See ECJ Judgment of 30 June 1993, Joined Cases C - 181/91 and C-248/91 Parliament v Council and Commission, ECLI:EU:C:1993:271; ECJ Judgment of 2 March 1994, Case C-316/91 Parliament v. Council, ECLI:EU:C:1994:76.

  101. 101.

    ECJ Judgment of 27 November 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, ECLI:EU:C:2012:756, para 158.

  102. 102.

    See ECJ Judgment of 27 November 2012, Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland , ECLI:EU:C:2012:756, para. 165.

  103. 103.

    As the ECB is provided with strong independence, the Advocate General has highlighted that the TESM cannot oblige it to perform specific tasks, but these must be accepted voluntarily. See See View of Advocate General Kokott delivered on 26 October 2012 (1) Case C-370/12, Thomas Pringle v Government of Ireland, ECLI:EU:C:2012:675, paras 180–181.

  104. 104.

    The involvement of EU institutions in the TSCG is less controversial. The Fiscal Compact does not modify the competences of EU institutions, but only integrates their functions. See Peroni (2012), p. 182. The tasks granted to the Commission are fully in line with its function of supervisor of European fiscal rules under the SGP . The involvement of the CJEU is also acceptable under the arbitration clause ex art. 273 TFEU being the object of the TSCG in wide party falling within the scope of the EU Treaties. More controversial is the setup of the Euro Summit , which may de facto undermine the prerogatives of the Ecofin Council and European Council in the process of economic coordination . On the involvement of EU institutions in the TSCG cf. Pistoia (2018), pp. 134–142.

  105. 105.

    See Hinarejos (2015), p. 75.

  106. 106.

    See Darvas and Leandro (2016), Efstathiou and Wolff (2018), European Parliament Briefing (2018), European Commission Communication (2018b) and European Commission Press Release (2019).

  107. 107.

    See Castaneda and Schwartz (2017); Eurostat, ‘Provision of deficit and debt data for 2017 - first notification’, 69/2018 – 23 April 2018.

  108. 108.

    See Haroutunian et al. (2018).

  109. 109.

    According to Adamski, a non-credible threat is a ‘threat that the player making it would not find optimal to actually undertake if called upon to do so’. Adamski (2016), p. 190.

  110. 110.

    On the scarce effectiveness of sanctions , see Amtenbirik and De Haan (2003), p. 1091; Louis (2004) pp. 577–579.

  111. 111.

    See Adamski (2012), pp. 1341–1342; Adamski (2016), pp. 191–192; Adamski (2018), p. 44.

  112. 112.

    See Chiti and Teixeira (2013), p. 689.

  113. 113.

    See Palmstorfer (2014), pp. 190–191; Allemand et al. (2016), p. 159.

  114. 114.

    Ibid.

  115. 115.

    This is especially true if we take into consideration secondary indicators, which have not been clearly specified. Although the choice of indicators is in some cases innovative, it still lacks a clear methodology. Most probably, the elaboration of the scoreboard has been more the result of a political compromise within the Council, than a coherent analysis of economic imbalances and their causes. See Solomos and Koumparoulis (2012), pp. 300–301; Kegels and Verlinden (2013), pp. 58–59, 62. On the weak application of the MIP see Adamski (2018), pp. 63–65.

  116. 116.

    ECJ Judgment of 13 July 2004 on the affair C-27/04, Commission v. Council, ECLI:EU:C:2004:436, para 80.

  117. 117.

    Council Decision of 21 January 2003 on the existence of an excessive deficit in Germany—Application of Article 104(6) of the Treaty establishing the European Community, (2003) OJ L 34/16; Council Decision of 3 June 2003 on the existence of an excessive deficit in France—application of Article 104(6) of the Treaty establishing the European Community, (2003) OJ L 165/29. On the case see Adamski (2018), pp. 38–41.

  118. 118.

    On the analysis of the case see Palmstorfer (2014), pp. 190–191; Tuori and Tuori (2014), pp. 105–106.

  119. 119.

    A sanction effectively adopted in the framework of the SGP was the fine imposed to Spain for the manipulation of statistics in accordance with art. 8 of Regulation (EU) No 1173/2011. Spain challenged the fine in the Case C-521/15. Cf. Chamon (2018).

  120. 120.

    On the soft approach adopted by the European Commission in the enforcement of the new rules of economic coordination see Adamski (2018), pp. 59–63.

  121. 121.

    See Council Recommendation for the necessary policy measures based on art. 121(4); Council Decision based on art. 126 (6) on the existence of an excessive deficit.

  122. 122.

    See Adamski (2012), pp. 1341–1342. On the possible equilibria within the Council for a RMV voting cf. Seikel (2016), pp. 1405–1408.

  123. 123.

    Fabbrini (2016), p. 61.

  124. 124.

    In order to work, the logic of the market needs that creditors are afraid of losing their money. Schepel (2017), pp. 81, 85.

  125. 125.

    See Louis (2010), p. 979; Estella (2016), p. 525. In this regard Menendez recalled Lon Fuller’s law: ‘you shall not pass laws impossible to comply with’. See Menendez (2014), p. 136.

  126. 126.

    See Hinarejos (2015), p. 57.

  127. 127.

    ECJ Judgment of 16 June 2015, Case C-62/14, Gauweiler (and Others) v. Deutscher Bundestag, ECLI:EU:C:2015:400, para. 72.

  128. 128.

    Schepel strongly criticised the correction of the market logic through the intervention of the ESM and the ECB . Schepel (2017), p. 96. On the transformation of the economic constitution from the market paradigm to conditional financial assistance see Ioannidis (2016), pp. 1263–1274. Tuori and Tuori speak of ‘constitutional mutation’ of the economic union also due to the strengthening of coordination, the widening of surveillance to macroeconomic imbalances and the setup of crisis management tools. See Tuori and Tuori (2014), p. 192.

  129. 129.

    Ohler (2011), p. 69.

  130. 130.

    Ibid. p. 69. For example, despite the IMF having declared that Greek debt had become unsustainable in 2016, the creditor countries of the ESM decided to continue financial assistance without demanding debt restructuration . Zettelmeyer (2018), p. 72.

  131. 131.

    Panizza (2014), p. 5; Audit (2014), pp. 218–220; Fuest et al. (2014), p. 311–312. According to Zettelmeyer the fact that the Greek debt restructuration was only partially successful proves the scarce effectiveness of CACs. Zettelmeyer (2018), p. 72.

  132. 132.

    Ibid., p. 71.

  133. 133.

    Ohler (2011), p. 69.

  134. 134.

    Audit (2014), p. 219.

  135. 135.

    European Commission Report (2017).

  136. 136.

    See Fromage and Dermine (2017). For an overlook of the different implementation of the TSCG see the EUI euro-crisis project report. www.eurocrisislaw.eui.eu.

  137. 137.

    ‘[A]s soon as France has ratified the Treaty and it has entered into force, the rules laid down in paragraph 1 of Article 3 will apply to it; […] pursuant to Article 55 of the Constitution, it will be hierarchically superior to legislation; […] it will be for the different organs of State to monitor the application of this Treaty, within the scope of their respective competences; [the] Parliament will be in particular required to comply with its provisions when enacting finance laws and social security financing laws’. Decision No 2012-653 DC of the Conseil Constitutionnel on 9 August 2012, para. 18.

  138. 138.

    European Commission Report (2017), p. 4.

  139. 139.

    See Fromage (2017), p. 124.

  140. 140.

    Ibid. pp. 128–130.

  141. 141.

    See Adamski (2018), pp. 66–69.

  142. 142.

    See Fromage (2017), pp. 133–136; Horvath (2018), pp. 517–518.

  143. 143.

    See Fromage (2017), p. 138.

  144. 144.

    Gros and Alcidi (2014), p. 2. On this topic cf. also Chalmers (2012), pp. 682–683; Menendez (2014), pp. 136–137.

  145. 145.

    See Fabbrini (2016), pp. 45–46.

  146. 146.

    Boggero and Annicchino (2014), p. 260.

  147. 147.

    Ibid. See also Adamski (2018), pp. 66–69.

  148. 148.

    See Gros and Alcidi (2014), p. 3.

  149. 149.

    The costs of the approved bailout consist of Ireland €40.2 billion; Greece €308 billions; Spain €100 billions; Portugal €52 billions; Cyprus €9 billions. See Estella (2016), pp. 507–508.

  150. 150.

    See Peroni (2012), pp. 167. See infra Sect. 5.6.3.1.

  151. 151.

    See supra Sect. 3.6.2.

  152. 152.

    Lo Schiavo (2017), pp. 140–142. More in general on the direct recapitalization instrument see Corti Varela (2015).

  153. 153.

    The empowering of creditor States was also encouraged by the introduction of RMV in the decision-making process regulating the MSP and the EDP . Menendez (2014), p. 135.

  154. 154.

    These are Germany, Estonia, Austria, Slovakia, Finland and the Netherlands.

  155. 155.

    See Hinarejos (2013), pp. 1632–1633.

  156. 156.

    ‘Cyprus successfully exits ESM programme’, ESM Press Release, 31 March 2016; ‘Post-Programme Surveillance report. Ireland , Autumn 2017’, 16 February 2018; ‘Statement by the staff of the European Commission and the European Central Bank following the ninth post-programme surveillance visit to Spain ,’ 16 April 2018; Statement by European Commission and European Central Bank staff following the Eight Post-Programme Surveillance mission to Portugal , 15 June 2018.

  157. 157.

    ‘Eurogroup statement on Greece ’, 15 June 2018. On the current economic situation in Greece see Avgouleas et al. (2018).

  158. 158.

    On the violation of human rights in the Member States following the application of austerity measures see Salomon (2015), Hinarejos (2016), p. 243; O’Gorman (2017).

  159. 159.

    On the negative consequences of austerity measures on the public opinion, social conditions and the economy see Tuori and Tuori (2014), pp. 235–236; Wilkinson (2015), p. 1072, Estella (2016), pp. 534–535.

  160. 160.

    See Bantekas and Vivien (2016), pp. 562–563.

  161. 161.

    See Tuori and Tuori (2014), pp. 189–190; Adamski (2016), p. 198; Murswiek (2016), pp. 51–52.

  162. 162.

    Hinarejos (2013), p. 1628.

  163. 163.

    Indeed, governments imposing heavy budget cuts are likely to lose the next general elections. Leino-Sandberg and Salminen (2017), p. 102.

  164. 164.

    See se art. 5(1) of Regulation (EC) No 1466/1997 and art. 2(5) of Regulation (EC) No 1467/1997.

  165. 165.

    See se art. 8(1) of Regulation (EU) No 1176/2011.

  166. 166.

    The communication in particular gives orientation to the application of the SGP by taking into account the cyclical fluctuation of the economy and giving margin of manoeuvre for the implementation of structural reforms and investments. European Commission Communication (2015). Cf. Pace (2018), pp. 109–110.

  167. 167.

    Costamagna (2015), pp. 132–138; Hinarejos (2016), p. 245.

  168. 168.

    In a new Communication adopted in 2018, the Commission gave a positive review of the use of flexibility in the last 3 years. See European Commission Communication (2018a).

  169. 169.

    ‘Figures illustrate how in Europe ‘speaking German’ is not necessarily ‘acting German’. Leino-Sandberg and Salminen (2017), pp. 102–103.

  170. 170.

    Regulation (EU) No 2017/2396 amending Regulations (EU) No 1316/2013 and (EU) 2015/1017 as regards the extension of the duration of the European Fund for Strategic Investments.

  171. 171.

    See Clayes and Leandro (2016), Rubio et al. (2016), p. 19.

  172. 172.

    Art. 5 of Regulation (EU) No 1017/2015 explains that projects shall be considered additional (i) if they ‘could not have been carried out in the period during which the EU guarantee can be used, or not to the same extent, by the EIB, the EIF or under existing Union financial instruments without EFSI support’; (ii) they ‘shall typically have a higher risk profile than projects supported by EIB normal operations.

  173. 173.

    This result can be partially explained considering the competition with the European Structural and Investment Funds and the weaker capacity to develop bankable projects and organise private public partnership, as well as the excessively small size of the projects. Cf. Rinaldi and Nuñez Ferrer (2017), p. 11.

  174. 174.

    Rinaldi and Nuñez Ferrer (2017), p. 10.

  175. 175.

    Huguenot-Noël and Zuleeg (2016) and Fernandes (2017).

  176. 176.

    See Inderst (2013), pp. 6–7; Tovo (2016), p. 387.

  177. 177.

    European Commission Communication (2015), pp. 7–8.

  178. 178.

    Ibid., p. 8.

  179. 179.

    European Commission Analytical Grids (2015), pp. 1–2.

  180. 180.

    Tovo (2016), p. 399; Rinaldi and Nuñez Ferrer (2017), p. 21.

  181. 181.

    Cf. Bénassy-Quéré et al. (2018), p. 6.

  182. 182.

    Ibid. p. 4.

  183. 183.

    ‘In times of stability it is possible that different coverage leads to depositors choosing the highest deposit protection rather than the deposit product best suited to them. It is possible that such different coverage results in competitive distortions in the internal market’. See Whereas (19) Directive 2014/49/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 16 April 2014 on deposit guarantee schemes Text with EEA relevance, (2014) OJ L 173/149.

  184. 184.

    In the transitional phase, until the Fund reaches the target level of resources, the SRB shall use the SRF in accordance with principles founded on a decision of the SRF into national compartments corresponding to each participating Member State, as well as on a progressive merger of the different funds raised at national level to be allocated to national compartments of the Fund. Cf. art. 77 of Regulation (EU) No 806/2014.

  185. 185.

    In some exceptional circumstances, the Fund may still be able to absorb losses (up to 5% of the total liabilities). Busch (2017), p. 463.

  186. 186.

    See Moloney (2014), p. 1628.

  187. 187.

    Busch (2017), p. 474. Art. 74 of Regulation (EU) No 806/2014 only foresees that the SRB shall contract for the SRF financial arrangements, including, where possible, public financial arrangements, regarding the immediate availability of additional financial means.

  188. 188.

    On the impact of the economic governance on the European social dimension see Costamagna (2014).

  189. 189.

    Bovens (2007), p. 450. On the issue of European democracy and accountability see Harlow (2002), Papadopoulos (2007), Bredt (2011) and Von Bogdandy (2012).

  190. 190.

    See Curtin (2016), pp. 183, 186, 190.

  191. 191.

    See Von Bogdandy (2012), p. 321.

  192. 192.

    According to Habermas citizens and peoples are the two constituent subjects of the European Union. Habermas (2012), p. 343. Accordingly, the Union is based on a dual structure of democratic legitimation: the EU citizens and the national peoples. Von Bogdandy (2012), p. 322. The community method complies with this ‘dual legitimacy concept’ as the legal acts shall be adopted by both the European Parliament and the Council. See Calliess (2016), p. 40.

  193. 193.

    See Starita (2017), pp. 19–24.

  194. 194.

    Lenaerts and Desomer (2002), p. 1222.

  195. 195.

    Scharpf (2003).

  196. 196.

    Schwarz (2014), pp. 403–404.

  197. 197.

    Starita (2017), p. 16.

  198. 198.

    For this reason, the German Federal Constitutional Court considered the fiscal autonomy of the Bundestag as a necessary element to protect the constitutional identity of the country. See German Federal Constitutional Court , Judgement, 30 June 2009, [2 BvE 2/08], para. 252; German Constitutional Court, Judgement, 7 September 2011, [2 BvR 987/10], paras. 38, 121–124. On the judgment of the Bundesverfassungsgericht see Rüffert (2011), pp. 847–849.

  199. 199.

    Cf. Ketterer (2016), pp. 263–264.

  200. 200.

    On the marginalisation of national parliaments see Chalmers (2012), pp. 685–687; Crum (2012), p. 622; Fasone (2014), Majone (2014), p. 1221; Martucci (2017), pp. 35–37. According to Jancic not all national parliaments have been ‘passive receivers’ of EU policies. On the contrary, some developed legal and political ways to mitigate the effects of such centralization. Furthermore, domestic parliament maintains some relevant soft powers: voting, scrutiny, information access and public debate. See Jančić (2016), pp. 242–245.

  201. 201.

    See Dawson and de Witte (2013), p. 834; Ioannidis (2014), p. 42.

  202. 202.

    In July 2015, the Greek government called a referendum to decide whether the country should have accepted the bailout conditions proposed by the Troika. Despite the majority rejected it, the governments decided after few days to sign a new MoU setting even harsher conditions for the bailout in order to avoid the exit from the monetary union.

  203. 203.

    On the possible exit from the monetary union cf. supra Sect. 2.4.7.3.

  204. 204.

    See Ioannidis (2016), p. 1277; Curtin (2016), p. 190.

  205. 205.

    Cf. Dawson and de Witte (2013), p. 834.

  206. 206.

    Majone (2014), p. 1221.

  207. 207.

    Daniele (2016), p. 270.

  208. 208.

    See Fasone (2014), p. 172.

  209. 209.

    See Starita (2017), pp. 23–24.

  210. 210.

    Art. 2ab(3) of Regulation (EC) No 1466/1997.

  211. 211.

    In the event the Commission and the Council refused to participate in the dialogue, the ECJ could be activated through a procedure for failure to act ex art. 265 TFEU. Fasone (2014), p. 176.

  212. 212.

    The President of the European Parliament shall be invited to the summits, while the President of the Euro Summit shall present a report to the European Parliament after each meeting.

  213. 213.

    The inter-parliamentary cooperation should work in accordance with the existing legal framework under EU primary law. See Protocol No 1 of the Lisbon Treaty on the role of national parliaments in the European Union. The role for the conference of national parliamentary committees (known in practice as ‘COSAC’), however, is not specified. De facto neither the European Parliament, nor national parliaments play a substantial role in the Fiscal Compact .

  214. 214.

    The SRB is in fact an EU agency. In particular the resolution scheme drafted by the Board enters into force only if, within 24 h after its adoption, there are no objections from the Commission or the Council. Cf. Art. 18 of Regulation (EU) No 806/2014.

  215. 215.

    The procedures involve the Commission, which shall make a proposal, and requires the approval of the European Parliament.

  216. 216.

    Cf. Fasone (2014), p. 184.

  217. 217.

    See Ioannidis (2014), p. 42; Curtin (2016), p. 191.

  218. 218.

    De la Parra identified other limits of the economic dialogue. First, many MEPs do not make optimal use of this new tools: either they don’t ask questions, but just criticism or they leave short margin for reply or just use the time given to enhance their visibility. Second, the debate has been characterised over the last years by the dispersion of questions, a scarce knowledge of the topic, vagueness of the answer. Third, the Eurogroup President attends meetings with the Parliament when it is more convenient for him and shall refuse to answer certain questions regarding the MoUs. See De La Parra (2017), pp. 116–118.

  219. 219.

    The chair and vice chair of the competent committee can be informed only in confidential way. See De La Parra (2017), p. 110.

  220. 220.

    See Ioannidis (2014), p. 39.

  221. 221.

    Art. 34 TESM provides for duties of professional secrecy for the Members or former Members of the Board of Governors and of the Board of Directors and any other persons who work or have worked for or in connection with the ESM. Furthermore, the minutes of the Board of Governors meetings are confidential in accordance with art. 17(6) of the ESM By-Laws. On the limited transparency of the ESM see Tuori and Tuori (2014), pp. 218–219; Hinarejos (2015), pp. 95–96; De Nes (2015), Ban and Seabrooke (2017), Simone (2017), pp. 205–208.

  222. 222.

    See Hinarejos (2015), p. 95; Daniele (2016), pp. 262–266; Pace (2018), p. 145.

  223. 223.

    Cf. Habermas (2015), pp. 550–551.

  224. 224.

    This is also testified by the more and more frequent meetings of the European Council: between February 2010 and January 2016 it met 41 times, while the Euro council 14 times. See Allemand (2017), p. 83. On the role of the European Council cf. Puetter (2016), pp. 258–262.

  225. 225.

    This is the reason why the European Council has become part of the economic dialogue with the European Parliament. See Allemand (2017), p. 84

  226. 226.

    Cf. Puetter (2016), p. 259.

  227. 227.

    See Allemand (2017), pp. 86–87.

  228. 228.

    Cf. Starita (2017), pp. 13–14.

  229. 229.

    Tuori and Tuori (2014), p. 217.

  230. 230.

    Cf. Menendez (2014), p. 133.

  231. 231.

    Other authors have a more positive interpretation of the role played by the European Commission in the governance. Cf. Bauer and Becker (2014). According to Daniele the strengthening of the intergovernmental method over the last few years has been balanced by the conferral of important advisory, preparatory and executive tasks to the Commission. See Daniele (2016), p. 271.

  232. 232.

    See Menendez (2014), p. 135.

  233. 233.

    Cf. Council Implementing Decision No 11554/16 on imposing a fine on Portugal for failure to take effective action to address an excessive deficit, OJ L 306/1; Council Implementing Decision No 11555/16 on imposing a fine on Spain for failure to take effective action to address an excessive deficit, OJ L 306/1.

  234. 234.

    Regardless the violation of its previous budgetary commitments, the European Commission decided to launch an EDP against Italy on the 19 December 2018. Dombrovskis (2018).

  235. 235.

    The surveillance model is based on a process of de-politicisation of fiscal and economic policy, which is considered a technical subject. In this perspective, national fiscal choices shall be taken within given objective parameters. Tuori and Tuori (2014), p. 211. In reality, the Commission can’t be completely impartial in the management of the governance, as technical decisions are influenced by political considerations. Allemand (2017), pp. 92–93.

  236. 236.

    See Crum (2012), pp. 622–623.

  237. 237.

    See Calliess (2012), pp. 109–110; Tuori and Tuori (2014), p. 179; Menendez (2014), p. 133.

  238. 238.

    On the necessity to strengthen democratic accountability at European level cf. Ruffert (2011), pp. 1801–1802; Baratta (2013), pp. 59–60.

  239. 239.

    Cf. Viterbo and Costamagna (2013) and Cafari Panico (2017), pp. 311–315.

  240. 240.

    Cf. Allemand and Martucci (2012), p. 455.

References

  • Adamski D (2012) National power games and structural failures in the European macroeconomic governance. Common Mark Law Rev 49:1319–1364

    Google Scholar 

  • Adamski D (2016) Economic policy coordination as a game involving economic stability and national sovereignty. Eur Law J 22:180–203

    Google Scholar 

  • Adamski D (2018) Redefining European economic integration. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Allemand F (2017) More or less intergovernmental cooperation within the new EMU? In: Daniele L, Simone R, Cisotta P (eds) Democracy in the EMU in the aftermath of the crisis. Springer, Berlin, pp 73–99

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Allemand F, Martucci F (2012) La nouvelle gouvernance économique européenne. Cahiers de droit européen 48:17–99, 409–457

    Google Scholar 

  • Allemand F, Bion M, Sauron J (2016) Gouverner la zone euro après la crise: l’exigence d’intégration. Gualino, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Amtenbirik A, De Haan J (2003) Economic governance in the European Union - fiscal policy discipline versus flexibility. Common Mark Law Rev 40:1057–1106

    Google Scholar 

  • Antpöhler C (2012) Emergenz der europäischen Wirtschaftsregierung - Das Six Pack als Zeichen supranationaler Leistungsfähigkeit. Zeitschrift für ausländisches öffentliches Recht und Völkerrecht 72:354–391

    Google Scholar 

  • Audit M (2014) A debt restructuration mechanism for European sovereigns: an emerging idea. In: Paulus CG (ed) A debt restructuring mechanism for sovereigns. Do we need a legal procedure? Beck-Hart-Nomos, Munich, pp 213–222

    Google Scholar 

  • Avgouleas E, Eichengreen B, Panizza U, Maduro M P, Portes R, di Mauro B W, Wyplosz C, Zettelmeyere J (2018) Independent report on the Greek official debt. CEPR Policy Insight No 92

    Google Scholar 

  • Ban C, Seabrooke L (2017) From crisis to stability. How to make the European stability mechanism transparent and accountable. Transparency International EU

    Google Scholar 

  • Bandilla R (2017) Artikel 25 AEUV. In: Grabitz E, Hilf M, Nettesheim M (eds) Das Recht der Europäischen Union. Beck, München

    Google Scholar 

  • Bantekas I, Vivien R (2016) The odiousness of Greek debt. Eur Law J 22:539–565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baratta R (2013) Legal issues of the fiscal compact in the euro crisis. In: De Witte B, Heritier A, Trechsel A (eds) The euro crisis and the state of European democracy, 2013. European University Institute, Florence, pp 31–63

    Google Scholar 

  • Bauer MW, Becker S (2014) The unexpected winner of the crisis: the European Commission’s strengthened role in economic governance. J Eur Integr 39:213–229

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck G (2014) The Court of Justice, the Bundesverfassungsgericht and legal reasoning during the euro crisis: the rule of law as a fair-weather phenomenon. Eur Public Law 20:539–566

    Google Scholar 

  • Bénassy-Quéré A, Brunnermeier M, Enderlein H, Farhi E, Fratzscher M, Fuest C, Gourinchas P, Martin P, Pisani-Ferry J, Rey H, Schnabel I, Véron N, Weder di Mauro B, Zettelmeyer J (2018) Reconciling risk sharing with market discipline: a constructive approach to euro area reform. CEPR Policy Insight No. 91

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernard C (2013) The carter in time of crisis: a case study of dismissal. In: Countouris N, Freedland M (eds) Resocialising Europe in a time of crisis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 250–277

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Beukers T (2013) The Eurozone crisis and the legitimacy of differentiated integration. In: De Witte B, Heritier A, Trechsel A (eds) The euro crisis and the state of European democracy, 2013. European University Institute, Florence, pp 7–30

    Google Scholar 

  • Boggero G, Annicchino P (2014) ‘Who will ever kick us out?’: Italy, the balanced budget rule and the implementation of the fiscal compact. Eur Public Law 20(2):247–261

    Google Scholar 

  • Borger V (2013a) The ESM and the European Court’s predicament in pringle. Ger Law J 14:113–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borger V (2013b) How the debt crisis exposes the development of solidarity in the euro area. Eur Const Law Rev 9:7–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Bovens M (2007) Analysing and assessing public accountability. A conceptual framework. Eur Law J 13:447–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bredt S (2011) Prospects and limits of democratic governance in the EU. Eur Law J 17:35–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Busch D (2017) Governance of the European Banking Union’s Single Resolution Mechanism. European Banking Institute Working Paper Series, No 9

    Google Scholar 

  • Cafari Panico R (2017) L’affievolimento dei diritti nella crisi economica e politica dell’Unione Europea. Studi sull’integrazione europea 12:289–316

    Google Scholar 

  • Calliess C (2011–2012) From fiscal compact to fiscal union? New rules for the Eurozone. Camb Yearb Eur Leg Stud 14:101–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calliess C (2016) The governance framework of the Eurozone and the need for a treaty reform. In: Fabbrini F, Ballin EH, Somsen H (eds) What form of government for the European Union and the Eurozone? Hart, Oxford, pp 37–56

    Google Scholar 

  • Castaneda JE, Schwartz P (2017) How functional is the Eurozone? An index of European economic integration through the single currency. Econ Aff:365–369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chalmers D (2012) The European redistributive state and a European law of struggle, the European redistributive state and a European law of struggle. Eur Law J 18:667–693

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chamon M (2018) Fining member states under the SGP, or how enforcement is different from implementation under Article 291 TFEU: Spain v. Council. Common Mark Law Rev 55:1495–1520

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiti E, Teixeira PG (2013) The constitutional implication of the European responses to the financial and public debt crisis. Common Mark Law Rev 50:683–708

    Google Scholar 

  • Cisotta R (2015) Financial stability and the reconstruction of the EU legal order in the aftermath of the crisis, in European Central Bank Legal Conference (2015), From Monetary Union to Banking Union, on the way to Capital Markets Union. New opportunities for European integration

    Google Scholar 

  • Clayes G, Leandro A (2016) Assessing the Juncker Plan after one year. Bruegel Blog Post, 17th May 2016

    Google Scholar 

  • Condinanzi M (2016) Unione economica e monetaria e politica sociale. In: Tizzano A (ed) Verso i 60 anni dai Trattati di Roma. Giappichelli, Torino, pp 241–252

    Google Scholar 

  • Corti Varela J (2015) Direct recapitalization of banks and sovereign debt: the ESM direct recapitalization instrument and its impact on sovereign debt. In: Hinojosa-Martmez LM, Beneyto JM (eds) European Banking Union. The new regime. Wolters Kluwer, Alphen aan den Rijn, pp 121–136

    Google Scholar 

  • Costamagna F (2014) The impact of stronger economic policy coordination on the European social dimension: issues of legitimacy. In: Adams M, Fabbrini F, Larouche P (eds) The constitutionalization of European budgetary constraints. Hart, Oxford, pp 359–378

    Google Scholar 

  • Costamagna F (2015) Il coordinamento delle politiche economiche nell’ambito del Semestre europeo. In: Porchia O (ed) Governance economica europea. Strumenti dell’Unione, rapporti con l’ordinamento internazionale e ricadute nell’ordinamento interno. Editoriale Scientifica, Napoli, pp 127–140

    Google Scholar 

  • Craig P (2012) The stability, coordination and governance treaty: principle, politics and pragmatism. Eur Law Rev 37:231–248

    Google Scholar 

  • Craig P (2013) Pringle legal reasoning, text, purpose and teleology. Maastricht J Eur Comp Law 20:3–11

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Craig P (2017) The euro group, power and accountability. Eur Law J 23:234–249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crum B (2012) Saving Europe at the cost of democracy. J Common Mark Stud 51:614–630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curtin D (2016) Democratic accountability of EU executive power: a reform agenda for parliament. In: Fabbrini F, Ballin EH, Somsen H (eds) What form of government for the European Union and the Eurozone. Hart, London, pp 171–194

    Google Scholar 

  • Daniele L (2016) Misure anti-crisi, riforma della governance della zona euro e assetto istituzionale della UEM. In: Tizzano A (ed) Verso i 60 anni dai Trattati di Roma. Giappichelli, Torino, pp 253–272

    Google Scholar 

  • Darvas Z, Leandro A (2016) Implementation of European Semester recommendations worsens further. Bruegel Blog Post, 15th June 2016

    Google Scholar 

  • Dawson M, de Witte F (2013) Constitutional balance in the EU after the euro-crisis. Mod Law Rev 76:817–844

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Gregorio Merino A (2012) Legal developments in the economic and monetary union during the debt crisis. Common Mark Law Rev 49:1613–1645

    Google Scholar 

  • De La Parra S (2017) The economic dialogue: an effective accountable mechanism. In: Daniele L, Simone R, Cisotta P (eds) Democracy in the EMU in the aftermath of the crisis. Springer, Berlin, pp 101–120

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • De Lhoneux E, Vassilopoulos C (2013) The European stability mechanism before the Court of Justice of the European Union. Comment to the Pringle case. Springer, London

    Google Scholar 

  • De Nes M (2015) The ESM and the principle of transparency. Perspect Federalism 7(3):128–141

    Google Scholar 

  • De Streel A, Etienne J (2012) Le Traité sur la stabilité, la coordination et la gouvernance au sein de l’Union économique et monétaire. Journal de droit européen 73:182–185

    Google Scholar 

  • De Witte B, Beukers T (2013) The Court of Justice approves the creation of the European stability mechanism outside the EU legal order: Pringle. Common Mark Law Rev 50:805–848

    Google Scholar 

  • Della Cananea G (2011) L’Unione Economica e monetaria vent’anni dopo: crisi e opportunità. Costituzionalismo.it. Issue No 3

    Google Scholar 

  • Dimopoulos A (2014) The use of international law as a tool for enhancing governance in the Eurozone and its impact on EU institutional integrity. In: Adams M, Fabbrini F, Larouche P (eds) The constitutionalization of European budgetary constraints. Hart, Oxford, pp 41–63

    Google Scholar 

  • Dombrovskis V (2018) Speech of Vice-President Valdis Dombrovskis: College read-out and remarks on the Italian budget, Brussels, 19th December 2018, SPEECH/18/6886

    Google Scholar 

  • Efstathiou K, Wolff G (2018) Is the European Semester effective and useful. Bruegel Policy Contribution No 9

    Google Scholar 

  • Estella A (2016) European Union bailouts and credibility: the constitutional dimension. Eur Public Law 22:507–540

    Google Scholar 

  • Estella A (2018) Legal foundations of EU economic governance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission Analytical Grids (2015) on the application of State aid rules to the financing of infrastructure projects. 21st September 2015

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission Communication (2015) Making the best use of the flexibility within the existing rules of the Stability and Growth Pact, COM(2015) 12 final

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission Communication (2018a) On the review of the flexibility under the Stability and Growth Pact, SWD (2018) 270final

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission Communication (2018b) On 2018 European Semester - Country-specific recommendations, COM(2018) 400 final

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission Green Paper (2011) On the feasibility of introducing Stability Bonds, 23rd November 2011, COM(2011) 818 final

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission Press Release (2019) Spring Package: Commission issues recommendations for Member States to advance sustainable and inclusive economic growth, IP/19/2813, 5th June 2019

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission Proposal for a Council Regulation (2017) On the establishment of the European Monetary Fund, 6th December 2017, COM/2017/0827 final

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission Report (2017) Report from the commission presented under article 8 of the treaty on stability, coordination and governance in the economic and monetary union, C/2017/ 1201 final

    Google Scholar 

  • European Parliament Briefing (2018) Country-specific recommendations, PE 624.404, 4th September 2018

    Google Scholar 

  • Fabbrini F (2016) Economic governance in Europe. Comparative paradoxes and constitutional challenges. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fasone A (2014) European economic governance and parliamentary representation. What place for the European Parliament? Eur Law J 20:164–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandes S (2017) Social Investment and the Juncker Plan, Notre Europe, Synthesis, 17th July 2017

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer-Lescano A, Oberndorfer L (2013) Fiskalvertrag und Unionsrecht. Neue Juristische Wochenschrift 65:9–14

    Google Scholar 

  • Fromage D (2017) Creation and reform of independent fiscal institutions in EU member states: incomplete and insufficient work in Progress? In: Beukers T, de Witte B, Kilpatrick C (eds) Constitutional change through euro-crisis law. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 108–142

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Fromage D, Dermine P (2017) The Commission’s report on the Fiscal Compact and its expected (cautious) assessment, Eufinacco, 31st March 2017

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuest C, Heinemann F, Schroeder C (2014) A Viable Insolvency Procedure for Sovereigns in the Euro area, ZEW Discussion Paper No. 14-053. Available at: http://ftp.zew.de/pub/zew-docs/dp/dp14053.pdf

  • Grimm H (2016) Zur Reform der Wirtschafts-und Wahrungsunion nach der Krise. Nomos, Baden-Baden

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gros D, Alcidi C (2014) The case of the disappearing Fiscal Compact, CEPS Commentary, 5th November 2014

    Google Scholar 

  • Habermas J (2012) The crisis of the European Union: a response. Eur J Int Law 23:335–348

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Habermas J (2015) Democracy in Europe: why the development of the EU into a transnational democracy is necessary and how it is possible. Eur Law J 21:546–557

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Häde U (2010) Kommissionsentwürfe für offensichtliche Ultra-vires-Akte. Europäische Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftsrecht 12:921–922

    Google Scholar 

  • Häde U (2012) Euro-Rettung zwischen Exekutivprimat und Parlamentsvorbehalt. Nomos, Badan-Baden

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Häde U (2016) Artikel 125 AEUV. In: Calliess C, Ruffert M (eds) EUV, AEUV, Kommentar. Beck, München

    Google Scholar 

  • Harlow C (2002) Accountability in the European Union. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Haroutunian S, Hauptmeier S, Leiner-Killinger N (2018) Country-specific recommendations for fiscal policies under the 2018 European Semester, ECB Economic Bulletin No 4

    Google Scholar 

  • Hentschelmann K (2011) Finanzhilfen im Lichte der No-Bailout Klausel – Eigenverantwortung und Solidarität in der Währungsunion, Europarecht, 282–312

    Google Scholar 

  • Herrmann C (2010) Griechische Tragödie – der währungsverfassungsrechtliche Rahmen für die Rettung, den Austritt oder den Ausschluss von überschuldeten Staaten aus der Eurozone. Europäische Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftsrecht 21:413–418

    Google Scholar 

  • Hinarejos A (2013) Fiscal federalism in the European Union: evolution and future choices for EMU. Common Mark Law Rev 51:1621–1642

    Google Scholar 

  • Hinarejos A (2015) The euro area crisis in constitutional perspective. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hinarejos A (2016) Changes to economic and monetary union and their effects on social policy. Int J Comp Labour Law Ind Relat 32:231–250

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffmeister H (2010–2011) To bail out or not to bail out? – legal aspects of the Greek crisis. Camb Yearb Eur Leg Stud 13:113–134

    Google Scholar 

  • Horvath M (2018) EU independent fiscal institutions: an assessment of potential effectiveness. J Common Mark Stud 56:504–519

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huguenot-Noël R, Zuleeg F (2016) Rethinking the EU’s investment strategy: EFSI 2.0 needs a Social Pillar to address economic insecurity. EPC Publications, 15 November 2016

    Google Scholar 

  • Inderst G (2013) Private Infrastructure Finance and Investment in Europe. EIB Working Papers No 2

    Google Scholar 

  • Ioannidis M (2014) EU financial assistance conditionality after “two pack”. Zeitschrift für ausländisches öffentliches Recht und Völkerrecht 74:1–44

    Google Scholar 

  • Ioannidis M (2016) Europe's new transformations: how the EU economic constitution changed during the Eurozone crisis. Common Mark Law Rev 53:1237–1282

    Google Scholar 

  • Jančić D (2016) National parliaments and EU fiscal integration. Eur Law J 22:225–249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kegels C, Verlinden J (2013) La détection et la correction des déséquilibres macroéconomiques. Reflets et perspectives de la vie économique 52:51–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kerber M (2013) Une apologie téléologique sans limites. Les Petites affiches, 7–11

    Google Scholar 

  • Ketterer L (2016) Zustimmungserfordernis beim Europaischen Stabilitaetsmechanismus. Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen

    Google Scholar 

  • Leino-Sandberg P, Salminen J (2017) A multi-level playing field for economic policy-making: does EU economic governance have impact? In: Beukers T, de Witte B, Kilpatrick C (eds) Constitutional change through euro-crisis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Lenaerts K, Desomer M (2002) New models of constitution-making in Europe: the quest for legitimacy. Common Mark Law Rev 39:1217–1253

    Google Scholar 

  • Lo Schiavo G (2017) The role of financial stability in EU law and policy. Wolters Kluwer, Alphen aan den Rijn

    Google Scholar 

  • Louis J (2004) The economic and monetary union: law and institutions. Common Mark Law Rev 41:575–608

    Google Scholar 

  • Louis J (2010) Guest editorial: the no-bailout clause and rescue packages. Common Mark Law Rev 47:971–986

    Google Scholar 

  • Majone G (2014) From regulatory state to a democratic default. J Common Mark Stud 52:1216–1223

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manzini P (2013) La riforma delle regole UE sulla sorveglianza dei bilanci pubblici nazionali. In: Adinolfi G, Vellano M (eds) La crisi del debito sovrano degli stati dell’area Euro. Giappichelli, Torino, pp 29–48

    Google Scholar 

  • Markakis M, Dermine P (2018) Bailout, the legal status of memoranda of understanding and the scope of application of the EU charter: Florescu. Common Mark Law Rev 55:643–671

    Google Scholar 

  • Martucci F (2017) The democratic foundations of the EMU. In: Daniele L, Simone R, Cisotta P (eds) Democracy in the EMU in the aftermath of the crisis. Springer, Berlin, pp 27–50

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Menendez AJ (2014) Editorial: a European Union in constitutional mutation? Eur Law J 20:127–141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miglio A (2015) L’Assegnazione di Compiti alle Istituzioni Europee nell’ambito di accordi internazionali tra Stati Membri. In: Porchia O (ed) Governance economica europea. Strumenti dell’Unione, rapporti con l’ordinamento internazionale e ricadute nell’ordinamento interno. Editoriale Scientifica, Napoli, pp 143–169

    Google Scholar 

  • Moloney N (2014) European banking union: assessing its risks and resilience. Common Mark Law Rev 51(6):1609–1670

    Google Scholar 

  • Munari F (2015) Da Pringle a Gauweiler: i tormentati anni dell’Unione monetaria e i loro effetti sull’ordinamento giuridico europeo. Il Diritto dell’Unione Europea, 723–755

    Google Scholar 

  • Munari F (2018) The European Monetary Union: a hard test for the rule of law within the EU legal system. Am Univ Int Law Rev 33:345–390

    Google Scholar 

  • Murswiek D (2016) Die Eurokrise vor dem Bundesverfassungsgericht. Nomos, Baden-Baden

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nettesheim M (2012) Staatshilfen aus der Sicht des Europarechts und der Verfassung. In: Kadelbach S (ed) Nach der Finanzkrise. Nomos, Baden-Baden, pp 31–78

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • O’Gorman R (2017) The failure of the troika to measure the impact of the economic adjustment programmes on the vulnerable. Leg Issues Econ Integr 44:265–291

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohler C (2011) The European stability mechanism: the long road to financial stability in the euro area. Ger Yearb Int Law 54:47–74

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohler C (2014) A governance crisis? Treaty change, fiscal union and the ECB. In: Ringe W, Huber PM (eds) Legal challenges in the global financial crisis: bail-outs, the euro and regulation. Hart, London, pp 121–130

    Google Scholar 

  • Pace LF (2018) Il regime giuridico dell’euro. La nascita dell'Unione economica e monetaria, la sua crisi e la risposta dell'Unione europea. Cacucci, Bari

    Google Scholar 

  • Palm U (2017) Artikel 136 AEUV. In: Grabitz E, Hilf M, Nettesheim M (eds) Das Recht der Europäischen Union. Beck, München

    Google Scholar 

  • Palmstorfer R (2014) The reverse majority voting under the ‘six pack’: a bad turn for the union? Eur Law J 20:186–203

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panizza U (2014) Do we need a mechanism for solving sovereign debt crises? A rule-based discussion. In: Paulus CG (ed) A debt restructuring mechanism for sovereigns. Do we need a legal procedure? Beck-Hart-Nomos, Munich, pp 223–240

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Papadopoulos Y (2007) Problems of democratic accountability in network and multilevel governance. Eur Law J 13:469–486

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peroni G (2012) La crisi dell’euro: limiti e rimedi dell’unione economica e monetaria. Giuffré, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Pistoia E (2018) Limiti all'integrazione differenziata dell'Unione europea. Cacucci, Bari

    Google Scholar 

  • Poulou A (2017) Financial assistance conditionality and human rights protection: what is the role of the EU charter of fundamental rights? Common Mark Law Rev 54:991–1025

    Google Scholar 

  • Puetter U (2016) New intergovernmentalism: the European council and its president. In: Fabbrini F, Ballin EH, Somsen H (eds) What form of government for the European Union and the Eurozone? Hart, Oxford, pp 253–270

    Google Scholar 

  • Richter C (2013) Article 125 TFEU. In: Geiger R, Khan D, Kotzur M (eds) European Union treaties: a commentary. Beck-Hart, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Rinaldi D, Nuñez Ferrer J (2017) The European Fund for Strategic Investments as a New Type of Budgetary Instrument, CEPS Research Report, No 07, April 2017

    Google Scholar 

  • Rossolillo G (2018) Fiscalità e sovranità: riflessioni sulla ripartizione delle competenze tra Stati membri e Union Europea. Il Diritto dell’Unione Europea, 123–152

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubio E, Rinaldi D, Pellerin-Carlin T (2016) Investment in Europe: making the best of the Juncker Plan with case Studies on digital infrastructure and energy efficiency. Jacques Delors Institute, Paris, April

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruffert M (2011) The European debt crisis and European Union law. Common Mark Law Rev 48:1777–1806

    Google Scholar 

  • Rüffert M (2011) Die Europäische Schuldenkrise vor dem Bundesverfassungsgericht – Anmerkung zum Urteil von 7 September 2011, Europarecht, 842–856

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruffert M (2013) Anmerkung Pringle-Urteil. JuristenZeitung 68:257–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salomon ME (2015) Of austerity, human rights and international institutions. Eur Law J 21:521–545

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scharpf FW (2003) Problem-Solving Effectiveness and Democratic Accountability in the EU. MPIfG Working Paper 03/1

    Google Scholar 

  • Schepel H (2017) The bank, the bond, and the bail-out: on the legal construction of market discipline in the Eurozone. J Law Soc 44:79–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwarz M (2014) A memorandum of misunderstanding – the doomed road of the European stability mechanism and a possible way out: enhanced cooperation. Common Mark Law Rev 51:389–424

    Google Scholar 

  • Seikel D (2016) Flexible austerity and supranational autonomy. The reformed excessive deficit procedure and the asymmetry between liberalization and social regulation in the EU. J Common Mark Stud 54:1398–1416

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simone P (2017) Respecting the democratic principle in ESM activities related to the context of the economic and financial crisis. In: Daniele L, Simone R, Cisotta P (eds) Democracy in the EMU in the aftermath of the crisis. Springer, Berlin, pp 195–214

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Smits R (2012) Correspondence: the European debt crisis and European Union law: comments and a call for action. Common Mark Law Rev 49:827–831

    Google Scholar 

  • Solomos D, Koumparoulis D (2012) The recent reform of European governance. Intereconomics 47:298–303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Starita M (2017) Democratic principles and the economic branch of the EMU. In: Daniele L, Simone R, Cisotta P (eds) Democracy in the EMU in the aftermath of the crisis. Springer, Berlin, pp 3–26

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Thymes D, Wendel M (2012) Preserver le Respect du Droit dans la Crise: La Cour de Justice, le MES and le Mythe du declin de la comunaute de droit. Cahiers de droit européen 48:733–757

    Google Scholar 

  • Tomkin J (2013) Contradiction, circumvention and conceptual gymnastics: the impact of the adoption of the TESM on the state of European democracy. In: De Witte B, Heritier A, Trechsel A (eds) The euro crisis and the state of European democracy, 2013. European University Institute, Florence, pp 64–82

    Google Scholar 

  • Tosato GL (2010) Il salvataggio della Grecia rispetta i Trattati? Affari internazionali, 21st May 2010

    Google Scholar 

  • Tosato GL (2012) L’integrazione Europea ai tempi della crisi dell’euro. Rivista di Diritto Internazionale, 681–703

    Google Scholar 

  • Tovo C (2016) Il Fondo europeo per gli investimenti strategici: statuto giuridico, profili istituzionali e funzionamento. Il Diritto dell’Unione Europea, 357–400

    Google Scholar 

  • Tufano ML (2002) Il principio di bail-out nel diritto comunitario. Il Diritto dell’Unione Europea, 505–517

    Google Scholar 

  • Tuori K (2012) The European financial crisis – Constitutional Aspects and implications. EUI Law Working Papers No 28

    Google Scholar 

  • Tuori K, Tuori K (2014) The Eurozone crisis. A constitutional analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Vellano M (2013) Il caso di Cipro come epilogo, ovvero prologo dell’ultima fase della crisi dell’area euro. In: Adinolfi G, Vellano M (eds) La crisi del debito sovrano degli stati dell’area Euro. Giappichelli, Torino, pp 227–238

    Google Scholar 

  • Viterbo A, Costamagna F (2013) L’impatto sociale della politica di condizionalità nel contesto della crisi dell’euro: profili giuridici. In: Napoletano N, Saccucci A (eds) Gestione internazionale delle emergenze globali. Scientica, Napoli, pp 167–194

    Google Scholar 

  • Vogel M (2012) Die europarechtliche Bewertung der Euro-Rettung. Zeitschrift für Staats- und Europawissenschaften 5:459–491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Bogdandy A (2012) The European lesson for international democracy:the significance of articles 9-12 EU treaty for international organisations. Eur J Int Law 23:315–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilkinson M (2015) The euro is irreversible! … or is it? on OMT, austerity and the threat of “Grexit”. Ger Law J 16:1049–1072

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zettelmeyer J (2018) Managing deep debt crises in the euro area: towards a feasible regime. Global Pol 9:70–79

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ziller J (2015) Il Quadro Costituzionale della Governance Economica Europea. In: Porchia O (ed) Governance Economica Europea. Editoriale Scientifica, Napoli, pp 13–31

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Lionello, L. (2020). Longstanding Sources of Instability: The Current Deficits of the Economic Union. In: The Pursuit of Stability of the Euro Area as a Whole. Studies in European Economic Law and Regulation, vol 18. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-28045-1_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-28045-1_4

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-28044-4

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-28045-1

  • eBook Packages: Law and CriminologyLaw and Criminology (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics